RELATIVE PRICE VARIABILITY:
The Case of
Hande KUCUK: Hande.Kucuk@tcmb.gov.tr
Burc TUGER: Burc.Tuger@tcmb.gov.tr
The Central
Bank of the
JEL Codes:
E44, E52, E63
Key Words: Relative Price Variability, Inflation,
Turkish Inflation
ABSTRACT:
In this study, the relation between inflation and relative price variability is
investigated to shed light on the inflationary dynamics in
Inflation
has become a part of many economies throughout the world. The interest in
dynamics and costs of inflation are still timely. In previous studies (e.g.
Fischer, 1981b), one of the main channels over which inflation may inflict
costs to the economy is relative prices. Analytically, relative price
variability does not necessarily reduce consumer welfare, however it leads to
inefficiencies in the allocation of resources that reduce real income (Fischer,
1981b). Given the significance of the costs associated with relative price
variability, the relation between that and inflation was extensively researched
and a positive relation between the two was documented for many countries for
varying time periods [3]. Studying relative price variability is valuable also
in terms of understanding the inflationary dynamics.
With
high inflation economies, more relevant and more common measure of variability
is relative inflation variability. Relative price variability basically
measures the degree of disproportion in a given price distribution. Given the
tradition, instead of calling this measure relative inflation variability, the
term relative price variability is used throughout the study.
In
our study, we investigate the relation between inflation and relative price
variability to have a better understanding of inflationary dynamics in
Our
study proceeds with a short literature survey of relative price variability
which illuminates the concept from an analytical point of view and provides the
motivation behind the study [5]. In the second section, the concept of relative
price variability is explained in detail and various relative price variability
measures based on different aspects of
CPI are calculated and examined. In the third section, the significance of the
relation between inflation and relative price variability is tested
empirically. In the last section, our main findings are summarized and some
further research agenda are suggested. The results of the unit root tests are
presented in detail in the appendix section.
“A
fundamental function of the price system is to transmit compactly, efficiently
and at low cost the information that economic agents need in order to decide
what to produce and how to produce it, or how to employ owned resources. The
relevant information is about relative prices- of one product relative to
another …- but the information in practice is transmitted in the form of
absolute prices (e.g. Prices in USD). If the price level is on the
average stable or changing at a steady rate, it is relatively easy to extract
signal from the observed absolute prices. The more volatile the rate of
inflation, the harder it becomes to extract the signal about the relative
prices from the absolute prices” ( By Hayek, as reported in
Friedman, 1977).
In the 1970’s, with the advent of high and variable inflation in industrial economies following the oil shocks, previous economic regularities were challenged. One example was the concept of the downward sloping Phillips curve, which relates inflation and unemployment in a non-linear fashion, being tested on analytical and empirical grounds (Friedman,1977). Furthermore, interest in the real costs of inflation surged. One of the main channels over which inflation may inflict problems upon the economy is by means of relative prices.
However
in models, such as by Lucas (1973), it was assumed that relative price
variability was independent from the variance of inflation. Analytically, it
was not possible to show the cost of inflation through relative price
variability. In Lucas’ model, each sector prices consisted of a general trend
component and a disturbance term (Vining,
Elwertowski,1976) :
|
|
|
Where
Pt distributed as |
|
|
Note that,
Pit
is the logarithm of the price of ith
commodity at time t, |
|
Pt
is the logarithm of the general
price level at time t and |
|
zt
is the random variable, independent of Pt. |
|
Pit-Pt=zt
where zt is distributed
as |
|
Variance in individual prices around their mean t2 is therefore independent of the degree of variability s2 in the general price level. This fact implies that variance in relative prices is independent of variability in general price level. Furthermore, if the terms above are expressed in terms of rate of change of price, this is equivalent to:
|
If the term on the right hand side is to be expanded, the cross terms will vanish:
|
That is, the variance in the one period change in Pit around the mean should be roughly constant and therefore unrelated to the degree of variability in the mean change.
In contrast to Lucas’ model, it was shown empirically that there is a positive and significant relation between s2 and t2. In other words, as the general price level becomes more unstable, dispersion in relative prices increases (Vining, Elwertowski,1976).
Analytical models were modified to account for this regularity between relative price variability and inflation. There are roughly three main possibilities consistent with the positive correlation between relative price variability and inflation (Wozniak,1998). These are models that predict that inflation causes relative price variability, a common third factor causes both inflation and relative price variability, and that relative price variability causes inflation [6].
II.1.a. Models That
Predict
i.) Menu Cost
Models
These models, mainly based on the work by Sheshinski and Weiss (1977), state that there is a lump sum cost of changing prices. These costs are associated with the transmission of price information to the consumers and the decision process itself. In the face of real cost of changing prices (menu cost), the optimum pricing policy is to change the prices at discrete intervals. The price setters will adjust the prices once the real price, implied by the level of inflation, falls below a threshold ‘s’. If real prices increase, the price setters will wait until the real price of the commodity they produce increases more than the upper bound ‘S’. The dispersion of the critical interval (s,S) across different products and the unsynchronized price setting behavior creates relative price dispersion. And as inflation is expected to increase, this band will get larger so that increased relative price variability will result. Therefore, from this model a positive relation between relative price variability and inflation results.
ii.) Contract
Models
Contract
models, example for which are Bordo(1980) and
The basic ingredient of this model is the long-term contracts. Long-term contracts may be desirable in the industries where it is important to minimize uncertainty and transaction costs. Uncertainties may arise due to unanticipated changes in the supply and demand conditions (Bordo, 1980). Transactions costs also arise because the search for and the gathering of information and the measures taken to avoid hazards of opportunistic behavior are costly. The existence of such contracts creates price stickiness. For example, a positive monetary shock causes all prices to increase but there is temporary change in relative prices because some prices adjust more rapidly than others. Thereby, with inflation, relative price variability will result due to the existence of long-term contracts. Moreover, this model also predicts that variance of relative prices, being regarded as a source of uncertainty, and contract length are inversely related.
II.1.b.
Common Third Factor Affecting Both P and RPV
i.)
Limited
Information Models [7]
This framework is mainly based on the ‘equilibrium misconceptions model’ by Lucas (1973) (Golob, 1993). As explained above Lucas’ original model failed to contain the empirical regularity between relative price variability and inflation. This was partly due to the fact that Lucas’ model was developed to explain the effect of inflation uncertainty on the output-inflation trade off. Later, Lucas’ model was adapted to the issue of relative price variability by Barro (1976), Hercowitz(1981), Cukierman(1983) (Golob,1993).
The analytical model was based on an economy with a single commodity; large distinct markets with continuous market clearing expectations are assumed to form rationally. The key idea behind the model is that agents confuse aggregate and relative price movements. This confusion, according to model, brings about the conclusion that ‘money is not a veil’ in the short run (Cukierman,1983).
Accordingly,
one example for the common factor that influence both inflation and relative
price variability is unanticipated changes in the money stock. If this change
in the money stock is fully perceived, then the relative prices do not change.
If there is misperception, changes in prices will be viewed as change in the
relative prices. Under the condition that demand and supply elasticities
differ across industries, economic agents perceive that relative price change
reflect actual price change (Fischer,1981). In fact, there is no change in
economic conditions. Therefore, agents acting upon misperception cause
misallocation of resources. Unanticipated change in the money stock will both
increase inflation and relative price variability.
ii.) Disturbances that have
macroeconomic consequences
Major supply shocks that typically occur in specific industries, together with differential rate of price adjustment of distinct industries lead to both inflation and relative price variability. Examples for these shocks are oil shock, or shocks to food prices due to climate conditions.
Table II.1: Selected Models Which
Predict A Relation Between RPV And Inflation
|
|||
MODEL |
Multi- Market Models
|
Contract
Models |
Menu Cost Models |
Selected
Studies |
Lucas(1973), Barro(1976), Hercowitz(1981), Cukierman (1983) |
Bordo(1980), |
Sheskinski and Weiss (1977) |
Key
Aspect Of The Model |
Imperfect information ß Aggregate/Local Confusion and Transitory/ Permanent Confusion |
Uncertainty ß Long
Term Contracts ß Price
Stickiness |
Real Costs associated with
changing prices (Menu Cost) ß (s,S)
pricing |
Alternative
Taxonomy of The Models |
Imperfect Information cum
equilibrium (Leiderman,1993) |
Imperfect Information cum
disequilibrium (Leiderman,1993) |
Perfect information cum
equilibrium (Leiderman,1993) |
Information based ( |
Contract based ( |
|
|
Transmission
Channel |
·
Unexpected
Nominal Shock ·
Variability
of Inflation ·
Unexpected
Inflation ß Relative Price Variability |
Nominal Shock (e.g. Positive
monetary shock) ß Some prices adjust more quickly
than others ß Relative Price Variability |
Even under full information,
the existence of cost of adjusting prices ß Prices are adjusted
discontinuously ß Even expected inflation
increases relative price variability. |
Macro vs. Micro |
Macro / Micro |
Macro |
Micro |
II.1.c.
Models That Predict
The last theoretical possibility that is consistent with a positive correlation between inflation and relative price variability is the case in which relative price variability is exogenous (Fischer, 1981). This assumption states that prices respond asymmetrically to the disturbances, so there is a positive relation between relative price variability and inflation. In this kind of model, goods markets are like Tobin-type labor markets. In these markets, when there is excess demand, prices increase. In case of excess supply prices do not fall. Thus, the larger the variability of relative disturbances, the higher is the inflation (Fischer, 1981).
II.2. Implications
of RPV Models and Previous Research on
II.2.a. Implications of RPV Models
In the 1970’s, relative price variability was studied within the developed economy experience for the real costs of inflation. Then, interest in this subject in the industrial countries started to wane after the inflation was brought down to single digits.
Table
II.2: The motivations
behind the studies related to Relative Price Variability in Different
Economies |
||||||||
§
1970’s Oil Shock §
Costs of Inflation §
Relative Price
Variability (Fischer,
1980) Developed Economies §
Hyperinflation §
High and Variable
Inflationary episodes (Blejer,1983; Blejer
et al.,1982) Developing
Economies Transition
Economies §
What drives
inflation? ß Role of
Administered prices §
Pass Through (Wozniak,
1998; Coorey et al, 1997) Disinflation
Episodes of Developing Economies §
Public Price
Freezes (Leiderman, 1998) |
The
subject of relative price variability was also taken up within the experiences
of the developing economies. In Latin American economies which experienced high
and variable inflation, the effect of inflation on the relative price
variability was investigated from the perspective of traded and non-traded
inflation (Blejer & Leiderman,
1982) and food inflation (Blejer,1983). Then the subject gained importance for
the transition economies of the
II.2.b. Previous
Research on RPV in
There
are some earlier studies on the Turkish inflation with reference to relative
price variability are mentioned in this part. In Alper
and Ucer’s 1998 study about inflation in
Karasulu’s 1998 study approaches the relative price variability concept from a microeconomic perspective, where the motivation of the study is to find out real costs of inflation. Micro data utilized in the study are from 3 big provinces and span the period between January 1991 and December 1996. In contrast to this study, Karasulu’s calculations take the cross-section dimension, the provinces, into account (Figure III.1), which helped for formal testing of micro models’ hypotheses and about the costs of inflation.
It should be noted that when the cross-section dimension of price indices are taken into account, one relative price variability measure is ‘within commodity group’ relative price variability; the other relative price variability measure is relative price variability ‘within provinces’, inter-market relative price variability.
As a
conclusion, it is pointed out that search costs within products increase from
the consumer’s point of view, with inflation. With inflation cost structure
loses its significance as a determinant of pricing decisions. These findings
are also in tune with Alper and Ucer’s
remark that “inflation appears to have taken a life of its own”.
Compared to Karasulu(1998), in Caglayan and Filiztekin’s 2001 study, a more comprehensive data set, spanning from 1948 to 1997, is employed. A total of 22 commodity group prices and 19 provinces are included in the calculation of relative price variability. A formal test of menu cost models vis-à-vis the signal extraction model (Barro,1976) is carried out [8].
In the empirical test of menu cost models, the direction of causality is expected from inflation to intra-market relative price variability whereas, in test of signal extraction models, the direction of causality is from unexpected inflation to inter-market relative price variability. In the Caglayan-Filiztekin study, it is concluded that the effect of inflation is non-neutral, i.e. there is a positive association between inflation and relative price variability, both inter and intra-market. Secondly, structural changes in the behavior of inflation are found to have a positive and important impact on the relationship. Finally, strong support for menu-cost models is found, however the data set does not support the signal extraction models.
III.1. Measures of
Relative Price Variability
The measure often used by researchers is the one suggested by Theil (1967) which can be calculated in the following manner:
Rate of change of the price of ith commodity is given by:
|
(1) |
Besides logarithmic difference of consumer price index (CPI) is also evaluated.
|
(2) |
From this individual and general rate of inflation we can get the relative price variability measure:
|
(3) |
Strictly speaking, (3) is a relative inflation measure, as the literature on relative price variability dates back to gold-standard era, these measures are called as relative price variability rather than relative inflation variability. We will also follow the tradition and call this measure as relative price variability rather than relative inflation variability.
This relative price variability measure is a divisia price index and the use of weights makes sense from the statistical point of view. If we were to draw n commodities at random in such a way that each TL spent of total expenditure has an equal chance of being selected, then the chance that commodity i will be selected is given by wit. Hence wit is the probability of finding the logarithmic price difference (Theil,1967, pp.136). Given the fact that (Dpit – DPt) is the rate of change of ith relative price –relative to the mean- and that the average of (Dpit – DPt) approximates to zero, this measure can be viewed as variance of relative inflation (Parks,1978). In other words, VRt can be interpreted as a measure of degree of non-proportionality of price movements (Theil, 1967).
Indeed, if all the prices in a given period increase at the same rate, the relative price variability measure will attain its minimum value, which is zero. As the degree of dispersion in the inflation rates increase, the VR measure will also increase. Besides, (3) does not depend on the general level of prices, it depends on the rate of inflation.
On the other hand, this measure suffers from shortcomings. VR cannot distinguish between relative prices that are appropriate for optimal allocation of resources and the ones that are mistakes. VR doubly penalizes a change in the relative inflation rate that is subsequently reversed. If there is permanent decline in the relative price of a good, the measure will change only once (Fischer, 1981). Also, in the presence of non-normality of inflation measures, as in the case of Turkish CPI in our analysis, there are potential problems with the second-moment of non-normal distributions (Blejer, 1983). To account for non-normal distribution a robust measure, which is independent from the central values of the distribution, was proposed by Blejer (1983) :
|
(4) |
The measure proposed by Blejer is a weighted average of the absolute values of all possible differences between the pair of observations. Given the complex formulation of the proposed measure, and difficulty in interpretation, this measure will not be calculated. Blejer (1983) postulates that the frequency distribution of individual rates of inflation approaches normality under the conditions of price stability or full price flexibility and simultaneous price adjustments, provided that the real shocks that have inflationary effects are distributed normally across commodities. However, in the presence of asymmetric price responses to nominal disturbances, the relative price probability distribution will be truncated or will tend to shift according to the nature of asymmetry (Blejer,1983). [9]
Following Blejer, distribution properties of month over month percentage change of unweighted sub-items of CPI-103 were investigated. Tests of normality, results of which are reported in the Appendix 1, revealed that the monthly inflation distribution has been non-normal throughout the sample period. Right skewness and excess kurtosis dominated over the sample period. [10] Note that the figures in the appendix table are based on unweighted measures, thus the mean given in the tables do not match with the official consumer inflation figures. Consumer Price Index (CPI), which is a Laspayres price index, is based on 1994 base year weights. Except from some sub-items, which exhibit seasonal price variations such as fresh fruits, vegetables and clothing, the weights of the commodities are fixed base year weights. Approximately 20 percent of CPI basket have time-varying weights while the remaining part have fixed weights (CBRT, 2001).
The
consumption bundle, upon which the CPI is based, is revised periodically to
account for the changes in the consumer preferences, quality in goods and
introduction of new commodities. Given this fact, the price index utilized
throughout this study is restricted to 1994 base CPI to ensure that the content
of the sub-items is stable. Monthly data spanning from February 1994 (94:02) to
December 2002 (
III.2.
Relative Price Variability Based on
Turkish CPI (103 Commodity Breakdown)
The approach to measuring relative price variability assumed different forms depending on the motivation of the particular study. From the point of view of inflationary dynamics, it sufficed to restrict the study to commodity-time space of CPI. For more micro oriented models dealing with the price setting behavior, it would be necessary to take the ‘province dimension’ of CPI data into account (Table II.1). [11]
Figure III.1: Dimensions Of CPI-103 |
|
To calculate a relative price variability measure, first the rate of change of prices is calculated for each 103 sub-item:
|
(1) |
Also the weighted mean rate of change, or the rate of change of CPI is calculated:
|
(2) |
Note that the logarithmic difference of ith subcomponent from CPI is a relative price measure, expressed in logarithms:
|
(5) |
Therefore the difference between Dpit and DPt will be a relative inflation measure.
|
(6) |
Where expected value of this relative inflation measure will approximate to zero. Therefore the variance of this relative inflation measure will be (7) which is nothing but the Theil’s relative price variability measure.
|
(7) |
Note that the weights used in the calculations are fixed base year weights. Given the fact that our data set has details up to four-digit commodity classification, time varying weights are not utilized in the computations.
In the following sections, relative price variability measures based on monthly inflation data will be investigated. Then we would look into the properties of the relative price variability measures based on seasonally adjusted data. As a second step, the horizon over which the relative price variability measures are computed will be lengthened to see the degree of price adjustment in a quarter and a year. As a third step we will compute the VR measures based on three different classifications of CPI: goods/services, traded/non-traded, administered/non-administered. In all these exercises, we will compare relative price variability with corresponding inflation measures.
III.2.a. VRt(103)
Relative price variability based on monthly inflation data, called as VR103 because it is based on 103 sub-items of CPI, mimics the behavior of monthly CPI inflation as can be seen from Graph III.1.a. The extreme values of CPI inflation are accompanied by high values of VR103. [12] Except from the coincidence of the peak values, it is difficult to analyze the relation with only a visual inspection.
Graph III.1: Relative Price Variability And Inflation |
|
a.) Monthly Inflation and VR103(mom) |
b.) Yearly Inflation and VR103(yoy) |
|
|
Source: SIS; Authors’ Calculations |
|
Graph III.1.b, which displays annual CPI inflation and annual relative price variability together, shows that the contemporaneous link between inflation and relative price variability is weaker compared to monthly measures. This is especially true for the period between 1995 and 1998. It is clearly seen that the two series even moved in opposite directions during 1998. Since 1999, it seems as though the relationship between annual inflation and annual VR103 strengthened as they moved in the same direction throughout both inflationary and disinflation periods. The graphs above also reveal that, both the monthly and annual measures of VR103 [13] increased more than the respective inflation rates in the post-crisis periods.
Graph III.2: Yearly and Monthly
Averages of VR103(MoM) and Inflation |
|
a.) Yearly Averages |
b.) Monthly Averages |
|
|
Source: SIS; Authors’ Calculations |
|
When looking at the yearly averages of VR103 we see that, except from 2002, when inflation increases, as does the VR103. [14] Besides, the VR103 takes on its highest value at the crisis period of 1994 (Graph III.2a).
As a next step, we investigate the monthly distribution of VR103 to see if the relative price variability is due to differential seasonal patterns of each sub-group price. Contrary to our preliminary finding of year averages, we see that in the summer season, when the rate of change of prices is low, the VR103 increases. This might indicate that relative price variability may result from different seasonal patterns of each sub-item (Graph III.2b).
III.2.b. VRt(103) Based on Seasonally Adjusted Data
The relative inflation measures based on raw data exhibits patterns pertaining to the seasonality of some sub-items in CPI and the price adjustments carried out by the public sector enterprises. To account for seasonality in some price indices, we used TRAMO-SEATS methodology by utilizing the Demetra program. Each price sub-component was investigated for seasonality. While 65 out of 103 sub-items which showed clear seasonal patterns were seasonally adjusted, in 38 items, no seasonality was found. Notably, seasonal adjustment failed for most of the sectors in which the prices are adjusted periodically.
Graph III.3: Yearly and Monthly Averages Of Seasonally Adjusted VR103 |
|
a.) Monthly Averages (1994:02-2002:12) |
b.) Yearly Averages |
|
|
Source: SIS; Authors’ Calculations |
|
When the series are seasonally adjusted, the relative price variability averages decrease to a great extent (Graph III.3a). This finding does support the view that one of the main sources of relative price variability is a different pattern of seasonality in the sub items of the CPI. However in April, even seasonally adjusted measure of VR103 is high, which points out to a factor, which increases relative price variability, other than seasonality. According to the yearly averages, positive association between relative price variability and inflation holds also for the seasonally adjusted figures, 2002 still being an exception (Graph III.3b).
III.2.c. VRt(103) Based on Different Time Horizons
Secondly, we calculate relative price variability measures over different time horizons. Previously, if the period of observation was extended, both the magnitude and the degree of fluctuations of differences over time would be substantially reduced (Blejer,1983). Graph III.4 supports this view, showing the differences between maximum and minimum rates of inflation for the 103 sub-items in the CPI on monthly, quarterly and annual bases. While the gap between the minimum and the maximum rates of change on a month-on-month basis is the highest, the gap narrows as we increase the period over which inflation is calculated.
Graph III.4: Percentage Difference between Minimum and Maximum Inflation Rate(*) |
|
Source: SIS, Authors’ calculations Note: a.)Over different time horizons, percentage difference is calculated by (max.-min.)/max. rate of inflation in CPI-103 in a given month , b.)Calculations are based on unweighted percentage changes |
To see the degree of price adjustment over different time horizons, quarterly, semi-annual and annual measures of relative price variability were also calculated. Graph III.5 reveals that relative price variability measured over three months is higher than that of measured over a month. This rather unexpected pattern shows that in a high inflationary environment, price signals are not clear for price setters even in three months. Interestingly, in 2000, when a crawling peg exchange rate regime was adopted, the pattern is in accordance with our expectations, in the sense that relative price variability decreased monotonically as the time horizon is expanded. In turn, this provides an evidence for the significance of exchange rate movements as a price signal. Another implication of Graph III.5 is that, even over a year, real inflation differential persists, implying an income transfer from one sector to the other due to inflation.
Graph III.5: Relative Price Variability Measures Based On Different Time Horizons(*) |
|
Source: SIS, Authors’ calculations Note: VR measures are clearly affected by the rate of
Inflation, which implies that relative price variability measure based on
month over month differences will be smaller. Therefore all the measures were
adjusted by the corresponding average rate of inflation. E.g., VR103(mom) at
1994:1 is ‘standardized’ with the mean of 1994:1 monthly inflation figures. |
III.2.d. VRt(103) Based on Different Classifications of
CPI
As a next step, we construct relative price variability measures based on different classification of CPI-103. We divide the items in CPI depending on following groups: food, beverages and Tobacco, Goods excluding these and Services, Traded vs. Non-Traded [15], and Administered vs. Non-administered classifications.
The
last two groups are based on the CBRT’s traded and
administered price classification while we generated the first classification
based on CPI-103 data. From each classification, one can observe if the
relative price variability differs across subgroups. From the first group we
would like to control for the most volatile part of the price indices, namely
the food. With the second group we would like to investigate the relation between
traded sector prices, relative price variability and exchange rate. With the
third classification we would like to see the dynamics of the public price
adjustments. The findings will shed light on the inflation dynamics in
In
contrast to the ungrouped data, the relative price variability formula for the
grouped data is more complicated (Blejer, 1983). Note that from each classification of CPI-103 we have a
different measure of total relative price variability -VR103, VR(GO), VR(T),
VR(Ad) (Table III.1)- these measures are
approximately equal to each other.
Table III.1: Different
Classifications of Relative Price Variability(RPV) Measures |
|||||
GROUP Name (G) |
Subgroups (gj) |
Table Representation |
RPV Measures |
||
Within RPV |
Between Group RPV |
Total RPV |
|||
Goods |
|
GO
|
|
VBt(GO) |
VRt(GO) |
|
Food, Beverages and
Tobacco |
FBT |
Vt(FBT) |
|
|
|
Services |
Ser |
Vt(Ser) |
|
|
|
Goods exc. Food,
Beverage and Tobacco |
GO |
Vt(GO) |
|
|
Traded |
|
T
|
|
VBt(T) |
VRt(T) |
|
Traded |
T |
Vt(T) |
|
|
|
Non-Traded |
NT |
Vt(NT) |
|
|
Administered |
|
Ad
|
|
VBt(Ad) |
VRt(Ad) |
|
Administered |
Ad |
Vt(Ad) |
|
|
|
Non-Administered |
N-Ad |
Vt(N-Ad) |
|
|
III.2.d.1. RPV In Food, Services, and Goods Excluding Food Sectors
Food,
beverages and tobacco (FBT), which constitute nearly 31 percent of the total
CPI, is one of the most volatile sub-groups in CPI. This is due, for example,
to the fact that food prices are mostly affected by supply conditions or
exogenous factors like weather. Inflation in the services sector, which mainly
consists of rent, transportation, health, education and communication services,
exhibits a more stable pattern over time compared to FBT sector. Goods prices are more sensitive to exchange
rate shocks or financial crises as the recent experience of
Table III.2: Inflation and Relative Price
Variability Within FBT, Services and Goods Excluding FBT Sectors (averages of
the monthly rates) |
||||||
|
Food,
Beverages and Tobacco |
Services
|
Goods
Excluding Food, Beverages and Tobacco |
|||
|
Vt(FBT) |
pFBT(%) |
Vt(Ser) |
pSer(%) |
Vt (Go) |
pGo(%) |
1994 |
0.0081 |
7.5 |
0.0033 |
5.7 |
0.0037 |
7.1 |
1995 |
0.0050 |
4.4 |
0.0024 |
4.9 |
0.0021 |
4.8 |
1996 |
0.0051 |
4.3 |
0.0029 |
5.0 |
0.0024 |
5.2 |
1997 |
0.0076 |
6.5 |
0.0022 |
5.7 |
0.0023 |
5.1 |
1998 |
0.0058 |
3.9 |
0.0022 |
5.3 |
0.0019 |
4.0 |
1999 |
0.0057 |
3.7 |
0.0018 |
5.1 |
0.0018 |
4.2 |
2000 |
0.0044 |
2.4 |
0.0007 |
3.2 |
0.0011 |
2.5 |
2001 |
0.0046 |
4.9 |
0.0014 |
3.3 |
0.0024 |
5.0 |
2002 |
0.0088 |
1.8 |
0.0010 |
2.2 |
0.0017 |
2.4 |
Source: SIS, Authors’ calculations Notes: Monthly inflation rates (%) for each group are calculated as the
logarithmic difference of the respective weighted indices times 100. |
It can be seen from Table III.2 that aside from a few exceptions, relative price variability moves in the same direction as the inflation rate for all the subgroups. The fact that the average relative price variability within the FBT sector was at its maximum in 2002, when the average monthly inflation rate in FBT sector was at its historical minimum is quite controversial. The same pattern remains even when beverages and tobacco are excluded. When the food item is analyzed down to its basic sub-indices, this huge rise in the relative price variability in FBT in 2002 was mainly due to the fresh vegetable and fruit items, which exhibited very low inflation rates compared to the other sub-indices of food that are less affected by the favorable supply conditions.
The
average monthly relative price variability within the goods excluding FBT
sector was highest in the economic crisis years of 1994 and 2001 and lowest in
the distinct disinflationary episodes of 2000 and
2002. This observation shows that goods prices are quite sensitive to economic
developments and that they are flexible. On the contrary, the services sector
prices show some rigidity. In the disinflationary
episode of 2000, the average monthly inflation rate in the services sector was
3.2 percent, which was well above the 2.5 percent average inflation rate in the
goods excluding FBT sector. On the other hand, while average inflation rate in
the goods sector doubled to become 5 percent in the following year of crisis,
the inflation rate in the services sector increased by only 0.1 points to
become 3.3 percent. Group variability in the services sector did not rise as
much as group variability in the goods sector excluding FBT sector in 2001 also
supports this view. In 2002, in both groups, relative price variability
measures declined relative to 2001 levels, but the fastest convergence to 2000
levels was in goods excluding FBT sector.
The fact that relative price variability measures were higher in 2002 than in 2000, although the average monthly inflation rate was lower in 2002, can be attributed to the drastic fall in domestic demand following the recession in 2001, which in turn increased the cost of adjusting (increasing) prices. What is more, in 2002, a floating exchange rate regime brought in an increased volatility in the exchange rates, which in turn led to further divergence in the speeds of adjustment of different sectors to the changes in the exchange rate. Firms faced a pre-announced exchange rate and a strong demand in 2000 and 2002, the cost of adjusting prices was much lower than in 2002.
Table III.3: Average Proportion of Total Relative Price
Variability (VRt(Go)) Accounted for by
Each Component (%) |
||||
|
l1*Vt(FBT)/VRt(Go) |
l2*Vt(Ser)/ VRt(Go) |
l3* Vt(Go)/ VRt(Go) |
VBt(Go)/ VRt(Go) |
1994 |
51.3 |
16.5 |
22.4 |
9.8 |
1995 |
51.7 |
20.1 |
24.2 |
4.0 |
1996 |
44.1 |
23.3 |
24.4 |
8.1 |
1997 |
55.0 |
16.8 |
20.1 |
8.1 |
1998 |
44.4 |
21.2 |
28.3 |
6.1 |
1999 |
49.6 |
18.0 |
24.9 |
7.6 |
2000 |
52.5 |
15.8 |
24.2 |
7.5 |
2001 |
42.1 |
13.9 |
30.6 |
13.5 |
2002* |
64.9 |
8.7 |
18.0 |
8.5 |
Source: Authors’ calculations Notes: a. λ1,
λ2 and λ 3 are respectively the shares of FBT, Services
and Goods Excluding FBT in total CPI, λ1+λ2+λ3=1 b. The within and between group
variability measures are calculated according to the formulas given in the
previous section (Equations 9-13). |
In
order to see what the sources of the fluctuations in the total relative price
variability, VRt(Go), are, we decomposed VRt(Go) to its components by multiplying the
within-group variability by the weight of that group in CPI (λi) and dividing it by total variability (VRt(Go)). Table III.3 shows that variability in
FBT, despite having the smallest weight, contributed the most to the relative
price variability. The between-group variability VBt(T)
has the smallest share. Accordingly, except for 2001, nearly 90% of the
variability in relative inflation rates is due to within-group variability. There
is a substantial increase in the share of between-group variability in 2001,
which implies that the pricing behavior across FBT, services, and goods
excluding FBT diverged considerably in 2001 and 2002. The share of λ2*Vt(Ser), which has been declining since 1999,
reached its minimum in 2002, while the share of λ1*Vt(FBT) has reached a record high because of
the reasons discussed above.
III.2.d.2. RPV In Traded and Non-Traded Goods and Services Sectors
To see whether there is a positive association between inflation and relative price variability within traded and non-traded sectors, we calculated the monthly averages of Vt(T), Vt(NT) and respective inflation rates. Table III.4 shows that there is indeed a positive association between relative price variability and inflation for the traded/non-traded classification notwithstanding a few exceptions, e.g. 1997 for non-traded, 2002 for traded [16].
Table III.4: Inflation and Relative Price Variability Within
Traded and Non-traded Sectors (averages of the monthly rates) |
||||||
|
Traded |
NonTraded |
Exchange Rate (USD) |
|||
|
Vt(T) |
pT |
Vt(NT) |
pNT |
Volatility |
Det |
1994 |
0.0046 |
7.3 |
0.0049 |
6.0 |
3.5 |
9.4 |
1995 |
0.0023 |
4.5 |
0.0029 |
5.0 |
1.3 |
3.5 |
1996 |
0.0026 |
4.7 |
0.0035 |
5.1 |
1.5 |
5.2 |
1997 |
0.0037 |
5.7 |
0.0028 |
5.8 |
1.6 |
5.5 |
1998 |
0.0024 |
4.1 |
0.0025 |
4.8 |
1.1 |
3.7 |
1999 |
0.0022 |
3.7 |
0.0030 |
5.1 |
1.4 |
4.6 |
2000 |
0.0020 |
2.5 |
0.0010 |
3.0 |
0.8 |
2.1 |
2001 |
0.0027 |
4.8 |
0.0023 |
3.9 |
4.1 |
7.1 |
2002* |
0.0033 |
2.2 |
0.0012 |
2.1 |
2.1 |
0.8 |
Source: CBRT,SIS,
Authors’ calculations
Notes: a. Monthly inflation rates (%) for each group are calculated as the
logarithmic difference of the respective weighted indices times 100. /b. Monthly volatility is calculated by dividing the standard
deviation of monthly exchange rate distribution by the mean of monthly
exchange rate
|
It is a widely accepted fact that in Turkey, not only the traded sector inflation, but the non-traded sector inflation is affected by the developments in the exchange rates as well [17]. Foreign inputs are used in the production of non-traded goods and services, and the exchange rate is one of the main determinants of the foreign input prices. In this context, it is not surprising to note that Vt(T) and Vt(NT) were at their minimum levels in 2000, in which, a crawling peg exchange rate regime with pre-announced daily exchange rates was being implemented. As a natural consequence of the fixed exchange rate regime, the volatility in the exchange rates was at its historical minimum in 2000 and the average monthly change in the US dollar was also at its lowest level up to that date. The association between Vt(T), Vt(NT) and the exchange rate is stronger for exchange rate volatility rather than the average monthly depreciation rate. Although the average monthly depreciation rate was lower in 2002 compared to 2000, the exchange rate was more volatile, possibly leading to a different degree of pass-through behavior for different sectors, which in turn increased relative price variability.
Graph III.6: Average Proportion of Total Relative Price Variability (VRt(T)) Accounted for by Each Component (%) |
|
Source: Authors’ calculations Notes: Traded and Non-traded shares are calculated as λ1*Vt(T)/VRt(T) and λ2*Vt(NT)/VRt(T) respectively, where λ1+λ2=1. |
III.2.d.3. RPV In Administered and Non-Administered Goods and
Services Sectors
Graph III.7: Inflation and Relative Price Variability Within Administered and Non-administered Goods and Services (averages of the monthly rates) |
|
a.) Administered Sector |
b.) Non-administered Sector |
|
|
Source: SIS; Authors’ Calculations Notes: Monthly inflation rates (%) for each group are calculated as the
logarithmic difference of the respective weighted indices times 100. |
Graph III.8: Monthly
Averages of Vt(Ad) and Vt(N-Ad) (1994-2002) |
|
Source: Authors’
calculations |
IV. EMPIRICAL FINDINGS ON
THE RELATION BETWEEN INFLATION AND RELATIVE PRICE VARIABILITY
The theoretical discussion presented above and the
examination of the Turkish data suggest a link between relative prive
variability and inflation. This section reports empirical evidence on the
relationship between relative price variability and variables related to
inflation such as the the rate of inflation, the acceleration of inflation, the
variance of inflation and the variance of the unexpected rate of inflation,
using model-free ordinary least squares equations. Although these equations are
good enough to test the significance of the relationship between relative price
variability and various measures of inflation, they essentially do not test one
theoretical model against the other.
Table IV.1: Pair wise Simple Correlation Coefficients
Between Relative Price Variability and Inflation Measures (1995:01-2002:12)
|
||
|
VR103
|
VR10
|
Monthly Inflation Rate ( |
0.53* |
0.48* |
Acceleration in Monthly Inflation
Rate ( |
0.49* |
0.43* |
Expected Inflation [19] ( |
0.04 |
0.29* |
Unexpected Inflation [20] ( |
0.28* |
0.16 |
6-month Variance of the Monthly
Inflation Rate ( |
0.16 |
0.14 |
6-month Variance of the Expected
Inflation Rate ( |
-0.07 |
-0.09 |
6-month Variance of the Unexpected
Inflation Rate ( |
0.10 |
0.04 |
Source: SIS,
authors’ calculations
|
||
Note:
(*) indicates that the correlation coefficients are statistically
significant.
|
As a first step, we calculated the pairwise simple
correlation coefficients for monthly relative price variability measures and
variables related to inflation at two different levels: 103 commodity breakdown
and 10 commodity breakdown [21], considering the earlier studies by Balk (1983)
and Goel and Kam (1993), which suggest that the level of commodity aggregation
may have a nontrivial effect on the relationship that is being tested. However,
the main measure is the one based on 103 commodity breakdown. The data used is
at monthly frequency and is based on Consumer Price Index, CPI, (SIS, 1994=base
year) in Turkey for the period between 1994 and 2002.
Table IV.1 shows that relative price variability measured
at both levels of aggregation are closely related to the monthly inflation rate
and the acceleration in the monthly inflation rate with high and significant
pair-wise correlation coefficients. While the correlation coefficient
between VR103 is and expected inflation is insignificant, the correlation
coefficient between VR10 and unexpected
inflation is positive and significant. On the other hand, the opposite is true
for VR10. Thus, the preliminary analysis presented by the correlation
coefficients imply that relative price variability measured at the lowest
degree of commodity aggregation is more closely related to unexpected inflation
rather than expected inflation.
As a second step, one investigates the direction of association
between relative price variability and inflation related variables before going
on with the regression analysis. For this purpose, Granger causality tests were
conducted, which essentially test whether there is a consistent lead and lag relationship between the
variables of interest temporally. In
the context of relative price variability and inflation, Granger causality
tests indicate whether changes in the
former typically precede changes in the latter or vice versa.
There is no unanimity as to the direction of causality
between inflation and relative price variability on both empirical and
theoretical grounds. For the case of Turkey, Alper and Ucer (1998) found that
there is no Granger causation between relative price variability and inflation
by using 21 commodity breakdown of WPI to measure variability. We held the
Granger tests for the monthly rates of inflation and relative price variability
at both levels of aggregation [22].
Table IV.2 : Results of the
Selected Granger Causality Tests (1994:02-2002:12) |
||||
|
|
|
Hypothesis
and Significance Level (p-value) |
|
Relative
Price Variability Measure |
Inflation
Measure |
Lag
Length |
Relative
price variability does not cause inflation |
Inflation
does not cause relative price variability |
VR103 |
|
4 |
0.54 |
0.13 |
|
|
6 |
0.45 |
0.09 |
|
|
8 |
0.67 |
0.00 |
VR10 |
|
4 |
0.69 |
0.55 |
|
|
6 |
0.54 |
0.14 |
|
|
8 |
0.71 |
0.05 |
Source: Monthly CPI (SIS, 1994=100) and
authors’ calculations using 103 and 10 commodity breakdown of the CPI between
1994:01 and 2002:12, SIS Manufacturing Industry Monthly Tendency Survey. Notes: a. The procedure is to regress each
variable on p lagged values of the other. If the right hand side variables
are jointly significant, they Granger cause the left-hand side variable. The
tests were done taking lag length p as 4, 6 and 8, keeping in mind that the
results of the tests may depend critically on the number of lagged terms
included. |
Table IV.2 presents the results of the Granger causality
tests for the monthly measures of relative price variability and inflation.
Taking into account that the direction of causality may be significantly
affected by the choice of the lag length, we report the test results for three
different lag lengths: 4, 6 and 8. We know that in Turkey, the adjustment in
prices is generally completed in 3 to 4 months. For example, the monthly
inflationary inertia is found to be significant up to 4 lags, the passthrough
is found to be completed in 4 months [23]. Keeping in mind the presence of
different supply and demand elasticities in different sectors and costs
associated with changing prices, we also allowed for the possibility of a
longer period of adjustment of 6 and 8 lags [24].
For VR103 and monthly inflation, when 4 and 6 lags are
involved, we see that the hypothesis monthly inflation does not cause VR103 is
rejected at 13% and 9% significance levels whereas the alternative hypothesis
is not rejected with very high p-values. When 8 lags are involved, monthly
inflation is found to Granger cause VR103 at a high significance level. Thus, combining
the results for all lags, we can
conclude that there is a one way causality running from the monthly inflation
rate to the monthly relative price variability measured at the lowest degree of
aggregation. This result is
also supported by the tests held on VR10 but more strongly when 8 lags are
included.
If we repeat the Granger causality tests for the
different classifications of CPI, , we see that for 4 different subgroups out
of 7, i.e. non-administered, food, services and non-traded sectors, the group inflation Granger causes the within group relative price
variability, whereas the vice versa is not true [25].
Having obtained some evidence supporting the view that
there is a one-way causality from inflation to relative price variability [26]
where we apply Fischer (1981) and Leiderman (1993) studies to test the
significance of the relationship between relative price variability and
inflation in Turkey, taking relative price variability as the dependent
variable. While we preserve the basic structure of their regressions, we extend
the analysis to control for the effect of degree of commodity aggregation on
the relationship being tested. For this purpose, as discussed above, we use two
measures of relative price variability -one based on 10, the other based on 103
commodity breakdown of CPI [27]. Thus,
the dependent variable that we use in the regressions differs according to CPI
commodity breakdown, while the explanatory variables do not since the relative
price variability measures based on both levels of aggregation are related to
the same consumer price inflation. Table
IV.3 present the results of the regressions linking measures of relative price
variability to the inflation rate and the rate of change of the inflation rate.
The absolute value of the rate of change in the inflation rate is also included
among the explanatory variables in order to test whether relative price
variability responds to the acceleration and deceleration in the inflation rate
asymmetrically.
Table IV.3 : Regressions Explaining
the Relative Price Variability with Inflation Rates, CPI (1994=100) for
period 2/1994 to 12/2002
|
|||||||||||||
|
Independent
Variables
|
Summary
Statistics
|
|||||||||||
R- No. |
|
Dependent Variable |
Inflation ratec |
Change in the inflation rate |
Absolute value of the change in
inflation rate |
Joint F-stat (pvalue) |
R2 |
DW |
RESET (pvalue) |
||||
3-1-1 |
|
VR103a |
0.0558 |
0.0001 |
0.0020 |
0.00 |
0.34 |
1.88 |
0.00 |
||||
|
|
|
(5.65) |
(0.19) |
(2.93) |
|
|
|
|
||||
3-1-2 |
|
VR103 |
0.0566 |
- |
0.0020 |
0.00 |
0.34 |
1.87 |
0.00 |
||||
|
|
|
(6.45) |
|
(2.93) |
|
|
|
|
||||
3-2-1 |
|
VR10 |
0.0159 |
0.0003 |
0.0002 |
0.00 |
0.25 |
2.23 |
0.15 |
||||
|
|
|
(4.19) |
(1.68) |
(0.78) |
|
|
|
|
||||
3-2-2 |
|
VR10 |
0.0162 |
0.0003 |
- |
0.00 |
0.25 |
2.19 |
0.07 |
||||
|
|
|
(4.29) |
(1.65) |
|
|
|
|
|
||||
Source: Monthly CPI (SIS, 1994=100) and
authors’ calculations using 103 and 10 commodity breakdown of the CPI between
1/1994 and 12/2002. Notes: a. Relative price variability
measure calculated using month over month rate of inflation. b. Values in parenthesis are
t-ratios |
|||||||||||||
The regression results presented in Table IV.3 verify the
significance of the relationship between the relative price variability and the
rate of inflation on a monthly basis for both levels of aggregation. The
coefficient of the monthly inflation rate is larger in case of the relative
price variability measure based on the 103 commodity breakdown (VR103). The
fact that the change in the inflation rate is not statistically significant in
explaining VR103 while its absolute value is, indicates that relative price
variability does not respond to the
acceleration or decceleration in the inflation rate asymmetrically. On the
other hand, the relative price variability measure based on the 10 commodity
breakdown VR10 is found to be unrelated to either the change in the inflation
rate or its absolute value.
Having shown the significance of the relationship between
relative price variability and inflation for all variability measures, we go on
with testing whether the positive association between the two is due only to
the effect of unexpected inflation or also to the direct effect of expected
inflation on relative price variability (Table IV.4). The first effect is
implied by the Lucas-type confusion [28] between aggregate and relative shocks.
Under rational expectations with market clearing and misperceptions,
unanticipated changes in the money stock lead to unanticipated changes in the
price level and increased relative price variability. According to this
approach, while fully perceived change in the money stock has no effect on
relative prices, a misperceived change in the money stock leads to changes in
prices in individual markets. Market participants, who view these changes as
changes in relative prices, adjust their own prices accordingly. This in turn
leads to actual relative price
changes given that the demand and supply elasticities in individual markets
differ [29]. The second effect, expected inflation having an effect on relative
price variability, is implied by the existence of costs of price adjustment
(Menu Cost Models). Taking the inflation rate as exogeneous and assuming that
there is a lump-sum cost of changing prices, prices change only at discrete
intervals. When there is a rise in the inflation rate, prices change more
frequently, but generally this is not enough to maintain the previous
dispersion of relative prices, which now widens. This menu-cost approach
implies that relative price variability increases with inflation whether it is
anticipated or not [30].
To test these hypothesis, an expected inflation series
was needed. We used two alternative expected inflation series in our
regressions. The first one is the quantitative inflation expectations of the
manufacturing industry taken from SIS Monthly Manufacturing Industry Tendency
Survey- denoted by
Table IV.4: Regressions Explaining the Relative
Price Variability with Expected and Unexpected Inflation, CPI (1994=100),
period 2/1994 to 12/2002 |
||||||||||||
|
Independent
Variables |
Summary
Statistics |
||||||||||
Reg. No. |
|
Dependent
Variable |
Expected Inflation |
Unexpected Inflation |
Absolute
value of Unexpected Inflation |
Joint F-stat (pvalue) |
R2 |
DW |
RESET (pvalue) |
|||
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
||||
4-1-1 |
|
VR103a |
0.069 |
|
0.010 |
|
0.012 |
|
0.00 |
0.37 |
1.68 |
0.00 |
|
|
|
(6.72) |
|
(0.35) |
|
(0.33) |
|
|
|
|
|
4-1-2 |
|
VR103 |
|
0.008 |
|
0.067 |
|
0.016 |
0.04 |
0.08 |
1.62 |
0.19 |
|
|
|
|
(0.64) |
|
(2.87) |
|
(0.42) |
|
|
|
|
4-2-1 |
|
VR10 |
0.018 |
|
0.016 |
|
0.005 |
|
0.00 |
0.23 |
2.11 |
0.01 |
|
|
|
(4.39) |
|
(1.47) |
|
(0.36) |
|
|
|
|
|
4-2-2 |
|
VR10 |
|
0.017 |
|
0.019 |
|
0.006 |
0.01 |
0.13 |
2.13 |
0.09 |
|
|
|
|
(2.81) |
|
(1.92) |
|
(0.39) |
|
|
|
|
Source: Monthly CPI (SIS, 1994=100) and
authors’ calculations using 103 and 10 commodity breakdown of the CPI between
1994:01 and 2002:12, SIS Manufacturing Industry Monthly Tendency Survey. Notes: a. Relative price variability measure
calculated by using month over month rate of inflation. b. c. d. Values in parentheses are
t-ratios |
According to the regression results presented in Table
IV.4,
In sum, the regressions presented in Table IV.4 could not
answer whether expected or unexpected inflation is more effective in explaining
relative price variability in Turkey. The results depend on what we use as
expected inflation. But, since expectations taken from the manufacturing
industry monthly tendency survey are only a proxy for CPI expectations,
the unexpected inflation series obtained in this way not only includes “the
expectation error” but also the structural difference between the CPI inflation
and the manufacturing sector inflation. Therefore, taking insample forecasts as
expected inflation seems more reliable, suggesting evidence in favor of the
Lucas-type aggregate-relative confusion approach for Turkey.
Additional analysis for monthly relative price variability
as a function of alternative measures of inflation variability following
Leiderman (1993): the moving (12-month) variances of the inflation rate, of the
expected inflation rate (manufacturing industry inflation expectations) and of
the unexpected inflation rate. Inflation variability, as measured in this
study, is found to have no significant effect on relative price variability.
V. SUMMARY AND CONCLUSION
This paper aimed to measure the relative price dispersion
in the Turkish Consumer Price Index (CPI) and verify the relationship between
relative price variability and inflation in Turkey for the period between
January 1994 and December 2002 from various aspects. Although no theoretical
alternative was tested against another, the results of the empirical analysis
were interpreted in line with the theories discussed briefly at the beginning.
In computing the relative price variability in Turkey,
measures based on seasonally adjusted data were also calculated in addition to
the measures based on raw data in order to control for the effect of seasonal
variation on the measure of relative price variability. Even though the monthly
measure of relative price variability decreases to a great extent when
seasonality is taken into account, it does not totally dissappear. This implies that there are factors other
than seasonality that lead to dispersion in relative inflation rates.
What is more, to control the effect of the time span on relative price variability,
quarterly semi-annual and annual relative price variability measures were calculated
in addition to the monthly measures. It was found that as the time horizon is
expanded, relative price variability measure first increases and then declines.
Although relative price variability is substantially reduced after six months,
the relative price adjustment is not completed in one year’s time.
To obtain inferences about relative price variability
across different classifications, relative price variability measures based on
different classifications of CPI were
calculated. The results showed that food is the sub-group that contributes the
most to the total relative price variability measured over food, goods
excluding food and services. In the case of traded and non-traded sectors,
traded sectors are found to account for the most part of the total relative
price variability based on this classification. The within variability in these
sub-groups were shown to be significantly affected by the volatility in the
exchange rate. When the administered and non-administered goods and services
classification was considered, it was found that the bulk of the public price
adjustments are generally realised in certain months, such as January and
April, leading to higher relative price variability in these months, whereas
the relative price dispersion is more evenly distributed across months in case
of the non-administered group.
The relationship between relative price variability and
inflation was verified both by the examination of the statistical properties of
the data and carrying out simple regressions. The results show that there is a positive contemporaneous
association between relative price variability and inflation in Turkey.
This conclusion is shown to be robust to the
degree of commodity aggregation since
there is a significant positive relationship between monthly measures of
relative price variability and inflation no matter if the former is measured by
103 or 10 commodity breakdown of the CPI. In addition, empirical findings
verified that monthly measures of relative price variability are found to
respond symmetrically to acceleration or deceleration in the inflation rates.
When inflation was decomposed into expected and
unexpected components to see which part of inflation is indeed effective on
relative price variability, it was found that the results depend on what is
used as expected inflation.
In our opinion, relative price variability reveals
valuable information about the inflation dynamics in Turkey. Differential
speeds of adjustment in different sectors and thus the role of relative prices
will gain more importance as inflation is targeted down to single digit levels.
High levels of relative price variability within some
sub-sectors imply that underlying inflation trend is masked by some extreme price
hikes in a given period. Therefore, following an inflation measure that
excludes these kinds of extreme values may be more informative than following a
general measure of inflation based on CPI, in terms of policy making. A further
research agenda, with these findings, can be investigating core inflation
measures, which would take the findings about relative price variability into
account, for policy making.
Another practical implication of excessive relative price
variability is related to forecasting inflation. With a high relative price
variability, treating sub-groups of CPI seperately may enhance the performance
of inflation forecasts. However this is an emprical problem which should be
tested against alternative methods of forecasting.
Endnotes
1) Authors would like to thank Zafer Yukseler, Hakan Kara for valuable
comments and also the colleagues in the Research Department of the Central Bank
for their contributions. The views expressed in this study are those of
authors, and should not be attributed to CBRT.
2) Research Department, The Central Bank of the
3) A survey of such studies can be found in Golob
(1993).
4) The period covered in the analysis is from January 1994 to December 2002
5) A more comprehensive literature survey can be found in Golob (1993), Fischer (1981) and Cukierman
(1983).
6) Alternative classifications of the models can be found in Cukierman (1983), Golob (1993), Leiderman (1993) and in Table II.1.
7) The other names for this group of models are multi-market models and
signal extraction models.
8) We have called the signal extraction model as limited information models
and multi-markets model (Table II.1)
9) The properties of price distribution for other countries are analyzed in
detail in a study by Roger (2000).
10) Please refer to the notes of Table A.1 in Appendix 1, for suggested
definitions of skewness and kurtosis.
11) Microeconomic analysis for
relative price variability for Turkey was carried earlier by Karasulu (1998), Caglayan and Filiztekin (2001) and Filiztekin
(2002).
12) The results of the outlier
detection procedure, in Appendix 2, shows that both monthly inflation rate and
VR103 have coincident outliers.
13) In this section, we derived VR103
based on annual inflation figures, from this point on, unless otherwise, VR103
stands for the relative price variability measure based on monthly inflation.
14) We will try to explain this
exception in 2002 when we discuss the relative price variability within
different subgroups of CPI.
15) The items in the CPI-103 list
that match with the exported and imported items in the Input-Output table of
1996 announced by the Sis are classified as traded and remaining as non-traded.
16) The negative relation between Vt(T)
and piT in 2002 is due to the fact that
traded sector includes the food item, which was analyzed in the previous
section.
17) The contemporaneous simple
correlation of the change in the US dollar with the traded sector inflation is
0.60, whereas the one with the non-traded inflation is 0.57 for the period
between January 1994 and December 2002.
18) This explains why the April
averages for both seasonally unadjusted and adjusted VR103 measures are so
high.
19) This series is obtained by using the insample
dynamic forecasts of a monthly inflation model which is specified as follows:
20) This series is obtained by
subtracting the expected rate of inflation from the realized monthly rate of
inflation (the residual series of the monthly inflation model described in the
previous note).
21) VR10 is calculated by using the
10 major sub-groups of CPI.
22) Since lead and lag relationships
are considered in these tests, we found it more appropriate to focus on monthly
measures of variability and inflation, as the lags of annual measures which are
obtained essentially by twelve order differencing do not seem to make economic
sense.
23) See Alper
and Ulcer (1998) for the former, Leigh and Rossi (2002) for the latter.
24) We did not rely on the
information criteria for choosing lag length because we thought economic
considerations outweigh econometric ones in this case.
25) There is no Granger causality
between the administered sector inflation and the relative price variability
within this sector, while for goods excluding food and traded sectors there is
a feedback mechanism between the inflation rates and the within variability
measures of the respective groups.
26) See Appendix 2 for the unit root
tests.
27) We also wanted to control for the
effect of “time” on the relationship by including the year-over-year relative
price variability and inflation measures following the argument of Bleejer (1983), which considered the possibility that
relative price variability is mainly affected by differential speeds of price
adjustment across different commodities.
However, since the year-over-year change in CPI is found to have a unit room,
while the relative price variability measures did not, the results of the OLS
regressions did not seem to be reliable (see Appendix 2). Thus, the results are not reported in this
paper.
28) These models are explained in
Table III.1 as multi-market models.
29) See Hercowitz
(1981) and Fischer (1981) for a detailed explanation.
30) See Sheshinski
and Weiss (1977) for an analysis focusing on the effect of the expected rate of
inflation on relative price variability.
31) The simple correlation
coefficient between manufacturing sector expected inflation and CPI inflation
is 0.79 for 1/1994 to 12/2002.
32) The simple correlation coefficient between expected inflation obtained
from monthly inflation model and CPI inflation is 0.87 for 1/1995 o 12/2002
(See endnote 14 for brief information about the monthly model.
33) Since the expected inflation
series are nonnegative their absolute values were not added to the regressions.
VI. REFERENCES
Alper, Emre C., Ucer, M. (1998), ‘Some Observations on
Turkish Inflation: A “Random Walk” Down the Past Decade’ Bogazici Journal: Review of Social, Economic and
Administrative Studies, Vol. 12, No.1, pp. 7-38 .
Balk, B.M. (1983), ‘Does There Exist a Relation between Inflation and Relative Price Change Variability? The Effect of Aggregate Level,’ Economics Letters, Vol. 13, pp. 173-180.
Barro, Robert J.
(1976), ‘Rational Expectations and the Role of Monetary Policy,’ Journal of
Monetary Economics, Vol. 2, pp. 1 - 32.
Blejer, Mario I
(1983), ‘On the Anatomy of Inflation,’ Journal of Money, Credit and Banking,
Vol. 15, No.4, pp. 469 - 482.
Blejer, M.I, Leiderman L. (1982), ‘Inflation and Relative Price Variability in
the Open Economy,’ European Economic Review, Vol. 18, pp. 387 - 402.
Bordo, Michael D.
(1980), ‘The Effects of Monetary Change on Relative Commodity Prices and the
Role of Long Term Contracts’ Journal of Political Economy, Vol. 88,
no:6 pp. 1088 - 1109.
CBRT Research Department (2001), ‘Core Inflation
Technical Committee Report’, Pub. No.2001/01 (In Turkish)
Coorey S., Mecagni M., Offerdal E. (1997), ‘Designing
Disinflation Programs in Transition Economies: The Implications for Relative
Price Adjustments,’ IMF Paper on Policy Analysis and Assessment, PPAA/97/1.
Cukierman, Alex (1983),
‘Relative Price Variability and Inflation: A Survey and Further Results,’
Carnegie-Rochester Conference Series on Public Policy, vol. 19, pp. 103-138.
Caglayan M., Filiztekin A. (2001), ‘Relative Price Variability and Inflation:
New Evidence from Turkey,’ Sabancı
University Discussion Paper series, no.2001-11.
Erlat, H. (2002), ‘Long Memory in Turkish Inflation Rates ’, in Kibritcioglu,
A., Rittenberg, L. and Selcuk
F. ed. Inflation and Disinflation in
Turkey: Ashgate Press, pp.97-122.
Filiztekin A. (2002), ‘A Preliminary
Investigation of Price Dispersion in
Fischer,
Fischer, Stanley (1981b) ‘Towards an Understanding Of The Cost of
Inflation: II’, Carnegie-Rochester Conference Series on Public Policy, Vol.
15, pp. 5 - 42.
Franses, P. H. , Haldrup
N. (1994) ‘The Effects of Additive Outliers on Tests of Unit Roots and Cointegration ’ Journal of Business and Economic
Statistics, Vol. 12, No. 4, pp. 471-478.
Friedman,
Goel, R. K., Kam R. (1993), ‘Inflation and Relative-Price Variability:the Effect of Commodity Aggregation,’
Applied Economics, Vol. 25 , pp. 703 - 709.
Golob, John E.
(1993), ‘Inflation, inflation uncertainity, and
Relative Price Variability: A Survey’ Federal Reserve Bank of Kansas City
Research Working Paper, RWP 93-15.
Hercowitz, Zvi (1981), ‘Money and Dispersion of Relative Prices,’
Journal of Political Economy, Vol. 89, no.2, pp. 328 - 356.
Karasulu, Meral (1998), ‘Relative Price Variability and Inflation:
Empirical Findings from
Leiderman, Leonardo
(1993), ‘Inflation and Disinflation : The Israeli
Experiment ’, The
Leigh, D., Rossi, M. (2002), ‘Exchange Rate
Pass-Through in
Lucas, Robert E.
Jr. (1973),
‘Some International Evidence on Output-Inflation Tradeoffs,’
American Economic Review, Vol. 63, pp. 326 - 334.
Parks, Richard W. (1978), ‘Inflation and Relative Price Variability,’
Journal of Political Economy, Vol. 86, no.1, pp. 79 - 96.
Roger, Scott (2000), ‘Relative prices, Inflation and Core
Inflation,’ IMF Working Paper, No: 00/58.
Sheshinski, E., Weiss,
Y. (1977), ‘Inflation and Costs of Price Adjustment,’ Review of Economic
Studies, Vol. 44, no. 2, pp. 287-304.
Taylor, John B. (1981), ‘On the Relation Between the Variability of
Inflation and the Average Inflation Rate,’ Carnegie-Rochester Conference
Series on Public Policy , Vol. 15, pp. 57 - 86.
Theil, Henri (1967), ‘Economics and Informartion Theory’, North Holland Publishing Co.
Vining D.R, Elwertowski T.C (1976), ‘The Relationship Between Relative Prices and
the General Price Level,’ American Economic Review, Vol. 66, pp. 699 - 708.
Vogelsang T. J (1999), ‘Two Simple Procedures
in for Testing for a Unit Root When There are Additive Outliers,’ Journal
of Times Series Analysis, Vol. 20, No. 2, pp. 237 - 252.
Wozniak, Przemyslaw (1998), ‘Relative Prices and
Inflation in
APPENDIX 1
Table A.1 : Selected Statistics
of the Distiribution of Monthly Inflation Rates
based on CPI-103 Series |
||||||||||
Obs. |
Mean(1)
|
Median |
Maximum |
Minimum |
Std. Dev. |
Skewness(2) |
Kurtosis(3) |
|
Jarque-Berra |
P-Value |
9402 |
4.7 |
4.3 |
23.7 |
-2.3 |
4.6 |
1.3 |
5.4 |
|
53.0 |
0.0 |
9403 |
5.2 |
4.4 |
39.4 |
0.0 |
5.7 |
3.2 |
17.7 |
|
1097.3 |
0.0 |
9404 |
28.3 |
24.4 |
88.9 |
0.0 |
20.2 |
1.1 |
4.2 |
|
28.7 |
0.0 |
9405 |
9.0 |
9.3 |
41.1 |
-7.4 |
8.1 |
0.6 |
4.1 |
|
11.9 |
0.0 |
9406 |
2.7 |
2.5 |
16.1 |
-18.8 |
4.6 |
-1.4 |
10.1 |
|
253.7 |
0.0 |
9407 |
4.4 |
2.5 |
72.7 |
-12.9 |
10.5 |
5.0 |
32.3 |
|
4108.8 |
0.0 |
9408 |
4.4 |
2.7 |
58.0 |
-21.0 |
9.4 |
3.1 |
19.4 |
|
1321.3 |
0.0 |
9409 |
5.6 |
4.4 |
53.8 |
0.0 |
6.9 |
3.7 |
25.2 |
|
2352.2 |
0.0 |
9410 |
5.6 |
3.6 |
46.5 |
0.0 |
6.9 |
2.7 |
14.1 |
|
659.2 |
0.0 |
9411 |
4.7 |
4.0 |
34.7 |
0.0 |
5.5 |
2.9 |
15.1 |
|
779.0 |
0.0 |
9412 |
6.5 |
4.4 |
40.6 |
-5.2 |
7.5 |
2.0 |
7.7 |
|
163.7 |
0.0 |
9501 |
9.4 |
6.6 |
123.0 |
-0.5 |
13.6 |
5.9 |
48.9 |
|
9665.0 |
0.0 |
9502 |
4.4 |
3.8 |
24.6 |
-9.4 |
5.2 |
1.3 |
5.7 |
|
60.9 |
0.0 |
9503 |
4.3 |
3.6 |
49.9 |
-11.0 |
6.0 |
4.6 |
35.1 |
|
4795.8 |
0.0 |
9504 |
6.2 |
4.1 |
96.5 |
-8.8 |
10.7 |
6.2 |
50.7 |
|
10427.3 |
0.0 |
9505 |
3.7 |
3.5 |
24.3 |
-18.6 |
4.4 |
0.1 |
12.7 |
|
402.2 |
0.0 |
9506 |
2.7 |
2.6 |
31.8 |
-19.8 |
5.0 |
0.6 |
18.3 |
|
1016.8 |
0.0 |
9507 |
3.3 |
2.5 |
24.7 |
-20.8 |
5.4 |
0.3 |
9.3 |
|
171.4 |
0.0 |
9508 |
5.3 |
4.1 |
32.1 |
-14.9 |
6.8 |
1.4 |
7.5 |
|
121.0 |
0.0 |
9509 |
8.5 |
4.2 |
133.0 |
-8.5 |
17.6 |
4.9 |
30.4 |
|
3637.0 |
0.0 |
9510 |
5.2 |
3.6 |
40.8 |
-3.3 |
6.5 |
2.3 |
10.7 |
|
341.5 |
0.0 |
9511 |
3.6 |
2.6 |
24.8 |
-5.5 |
4.2 |
2.0 |
9.6 |
|
260.1 |
0.0 |
9512 |
3.3 |
2.7 |
19.5 |
-2.2 |
3.7 |
2.1 |
8.9 |
|
223.3 |
0.0 |
9601 |
8.7 |
6.6 |
53.2 |
-7.4 |
8.8 |
1.9 |
8.7 |
|
201.6 |
0.0 |
9602 |
5.3 |
4.3 |
53.2 |
-12.7 |
7.4 |
3.3 |
20.6 |
|
1506.9 |
0.0 |
9603 |
6.6 |
4.0 |
66.1 |
-1.3 |
9.6 |
3.7 |
20.0 |
|
1478.6 |
0.0 |
9604 |
6.2 |
4.7 |
42.8 |
-8.6 |
6.7 |
2.2 |
11.4 |
|
382.2 |
0.0 |
9605 |
5.6 |
4.3 |
47.1 |
-13.2 |
7.2 |
2.5 |
13.9 |
|
617.2 |
0.0 |
9606 |
3.3 |
2.8 |
46.1 |
-17.3 |
6.1 |
3.0 |
26.7 |
|
2559.7 |
0.0 |
9607 |
3.6 |
2.9 |
23.0 |
-25.2 |
6.2 |
-0.1 |
9.2 |
|
164.7 |
0.0 |
9608 |
5.9 |
3.7 |
81.5 |
-2.6 |
9.6 |
5.3 |
39.1 |
|
6076.1 |
0.0 |
9609 |
6.2 |
3.8 |
100.0 |
-5.7 |
12.3 |
5.4 |
37.1 |
|
5489.4 |
0.0 |
9610 |
5.4 |
4.7 |
23.0 |
-11.9 |
5.6 |
1.0 |
4.8 |
|
29.9 |
0.0 |
9611 |
3.6 |
2.9 |
33.5 |
-10.4 |
5.0 |
2.9 |
17.3 |
|
1015.0 |
0.0 |
9612 |
3.6 |
3.3 |
23.3 |
-6.4 |
4.0 |
2.1 |
10.5 |
|
319.9 |
0.0 |
9701 |
7.2 |
5.0 |
43.8 |
-3.3 |
8.5 |
2.3 |
8.8 |
|
232.0 |
0.0 |
9702 |
6.4 |
4.3 |
96.6 |
-4.0 |
11.4 |
5.6 |
41.7 |
|
6958.4 |
0.0 |
9703 |
5.3 |
4.2 |
25.5 |
-0.6 |
5.0 |
1.6 |
6.3 |
|
93.1 |
0.0 |
9704 |
5.3 |
4.0 |
37.9 |
0.0 |
6.1 |
2.7 |
12.4 |
|
503.5 |
0.0 |
9705 |
5.8 |
4.7 |
43.5 |
-18.9 |
7.8 |
2.1 |
11.3 |
|
373.1 |
0.0 |
9706 |
3.2 |
2.8 |
49.7 |
-17.9 |
6.5 |
3.2 |
28.9 |
|
3053.8 |
0.0 |
9707 |
6.6 |
5.5 |
42.0 |
-14.0 |
8.7 |
1.5 |
7.1 |
|
112.5 |
0.0 |
9708 |
7.3 |
5.6 |
107.0 |
-15.5 |
12.1 |
5.7 |
46.9 |
|
8833.3 |
0.0 |
9709 |
9.3 |
7.0 |
100.0 |
-12.8 |
12.9 |
4.6 |
28.8 |
|
3220.9 |
0.0 |
9710 |
7.3 |
6.2 |
43.1 |
-2.7 |
7.8 |
2.0 |
8.2 |
|
184.1 |
0.0 |
9711 |
5.4 |
4.8 |
41.8 |
-17.4 |
7.3 |
2.2 |
11.8 |
|
419.7 |
0.0 |
9712 |
4.4 |
4.4 |
17.4 |
-1.8 |
3.5 |
0.8 |
3.9 |
|
14.2 |
0.0 |
Source: SIS, Authors’ calculations
Note: 1.)Since the statistics are based on unweighted
measures, mean is not equal to published monthly inflation figures.
2.) Skewness is a
measure of asymetry of the distribution of the series
around its mean. The skewness of a symetric distribution such as the normal distribution is
zero. Positive skewness means that the
distribution has a long tail. And negative skewness
means that the distribution has a long left tail (Eviews
4.0 User’s Guide).
3.) Kurtosis measures the peakedness or flatness of the distribution of the series. Kurtosis
of the normal distribution is 3. If the kurtosis exceeds 3 the distribution
is peaked (leptokurtic) relative to the
(*)Obs. |
Mean(1)
|
Median |
Maximum |
Minimum |
Std. Dev. |
Skewness(2) |
Kurtosis(3) |
|
Jarque-Berra |
P-Value |
9801 |
7.3 |
5.6 |
48.5 |
-2.0 |
8.5 |
2.4 |
9.9 |
|
306.6 |
0.0 |
9802 |
4.9 |
4.1 |
49.6 |
-4.8 |
6.6 |
3.5 |
22.2 |
|
1785.7 |
0.0 |
9803 |
5.3 |
4.2 |
33.1 |
-0.5 |
6.1 |
2.6 |
11.2 |
|
406.4 |
0.0 |
9804 |
4.7 |
3.8 |
24.1 |
-0.7 |
4.7 |
1.5 |
5.8 |
|
72.9 |
0.0 |
9805 |
3.7 |
3.2 |
24.6 |
-19.2 |
5.2 |
0.3 |
10.9 |
|
269.3 |
0.0 |
9806 |
3.9 |
3.4 |
46.7 |
-41.6 |
7.5 |
0.0 |
25.3 |
|
2137.1 |
0.0 |
9807 |
4.2 |
3.4 |
34.8 |
-11.6 |
6.4 |
2.1 |
10.5 |
|
316.2 |
0.0 |
9808 |
5.3 |
3.0 |
106.7 |
-21.2 |
15.1 |
5.2 |
32.9 |
|
4314.3 |
0.0 |
9809 |
7.1 |
4.1 |
103.0 |
-2.9 |
12.0 |
5.9 |
43.9 |
|
7757.4 |
0.0 |
9810 |
4.5 |
3.3 |
35.4 |
-6.6 |
5.7 |
2.5 |
12.0 |
|
452.5 |
0.0 |
9811 |
3.8 |
3.1 |
41.1 |
-3.6 |
5.1 |
4.1 |
29.3 |
|
3265.9 |
0.0 |
9812 |
2.3 |
2.0 |
11.1 |
-8.8 |
2.6 |
0.2 |
6.2 |
|
43.8 |
0.0 |
9901 |
5.2 |
3.7 |
33.7 |
-6.0 |
6.5 |
2.0 |
7.8 |
|
168.2 |
0.0 |
9902 |
3.6 |
2.8 |
27.0 |
-4.8 |
5.0 |
2.3 |
9.9 |
|
295.5 |
0.0 |
9903 |
4.5 |
3.0 |
80.7 |
-2.5 |
8.8 |
6.7 |
57.3 |
|
13411.8 |
0.0 |
9904 |
3.6 |
2.8 |
36.9 |
-3.1 |
5.1 |
3.9 |
23.7 |
|
2111.8 |
0.0 |
9905 |
3.2 |
3.4 |
13.0 |
-26.0 |
4.0 |
-3.4 |
28.4 |
|
2962.3 |
0.0 |
9906 |
3.4 |
3.0 |
31.9 |
-27.7 |
5.9 |
-0.5 |
14.9 |
|
609.1 |
0.0 |
9907 |
5.1 |
3.1 |
77.0 |
-17.8 |
9.4 |
4.6 |
35.7 |
|
4949.2 |
0.0 |
9908 |
4.2 |
2.7 |
78.5 |
-6.4 |
10.7 |
5.9 |
39.6 |
|
6333.8 |
0.0 |
9909 |
7.5 |
4.0 |
91.5 |
-0.6 |
12.3 |
4.4 |
26.2 |
|
2627.9 |
0.0 |
9910 |
4.8 |
3.7 |
26.8 |
-1.1 |
5.2 |
1.9 |
7.3 |
|
140.0 |
0.0 |
9911 |
3.0 |
2.7 |
17.5 |
-2.4 |
3.0 |
1.6 |
8.0 |
|
153.4 |
0.0 |
9912 |
7.5 |
4.3 |
100.0 |
-5.3 |
14.8 |
4.6 |
25.4 |
|
2518.7 |
0.0 |
0001 |
6.1 |
4.4 |
79.5 |
-4.9 |
9.1 |
5.4 |
43.2 |
|
7424.8 |
0.0 |
0002 |
3.2 |
2.9 |
29.1 |
-5.5 |
4.2 |
2.6 |
16.4 |
|
880.4 |
0.0 |
0003 |
2.7 |
2.1 |
22.3 |
-2.7 |
3.7 |
3.0 |
14.0 |
|
674.0 |
0.0 |
0004 |
2.3 |
2.1 |
15.5 |
-16.5 |
4.2 |
-0.9 |
10.6 |
|
260.3 |
0.0 |
0005 |
2.4 |
2.1 |
20.2 |
-14.3 |
4.1 |
1.1 |
11.6 |
|
336.1 |
0.0 |
0006 |
1.2 |
1.2 |
19.6 |
-41.5 |
5.0 |
-5.6 |
54.4 |
|
11897.8 |
0.0 |
0007 |
2.5 |
1.4 |
21.2 |
-6.6 |
4.0 |
2.2 |
9.5 |
|
263.4 |
0.0 |
0008 |
2.6 |
1.5 |
40.1 |
-12.3 |
6.0 |
4.0 |
23.7 |
|
2118.1 |
0.0 |
0009 |
3.0 |
2.2 |
24.6 |
-8.5 |
4.0 |
2.5 |
13.3 |
|
563.0 |
0.0 |
0010 |
2.7 |
1.9 |
18.2 |
-2.7 |
3.6 |
2.0 |
8.0 |
|
177.0 |
0.0 |
0011 |
3.2 |
2.2 |
20.9 |
-3.8 |
3.9 |
2.1 |
8.6 |
|
206.9 |
0.0 |
0012 |
1.7 |
1.3 |
7.0 |
-0.7 |
1.8 |
1.2 |
3.8 |
|
26.1 |
0.0 |
0101 |
3.0 |
1.8 |
51.1 |
-6.6 |
6.0 |
5.2 |
41.7 |
|
6906.0 |
0.0 |
0102 |
2.1 |
1.5 |
25.0 |
-5.1 |
3.9 |
2.9 |
16.9 |
|
975.1 |
0.0 |
0103 |
6.6 |
5.2 |
31.3 |
-0.7 |
6.4 |
1.6 |
5.5 |
|
67.7 |
0.0 |
0104 |
10.9 |
11.0 |
44.3 |
-2.9 |
8.2 |
0.9 |
5.0 |
|
32.3 |
0.0 |
0105 |
6.0 |
5.1 |
50.0 |
-8.1 |
6.7 |
3.0 |
20.1 |
|
1405.8 |
0.0 |
0106 |
3.5 |
2.3 |
21.4 |
-8.9 |
4.9 |
1.5 |
6.7 |
|
96.5 |
0.0 |
0107 |
2.5 |
2.3 |
15.6 |
-13.2 |
3.8 |
0.3 |
6.6 |
|
57.7 |
0.0 |
0108 |
4.3 |
2.9 |
59.5 |
-25.5 |
8.4 |
3.4 |
25.0 |
|
2274.8 |
0.0 |
0109 |
6.2 |
4.4 |
56.3 |
-1.7 |
7.9 |
3.4 |
18.7 |
|
1252.1 |
0.0 |
0110 |
5.6 |
4.6 |
34.8 |
-14.7 |
6.1 |
1.3 |
8.5 |
|
157.0 |
0.0 |
0111 |
4.1 |
3.6 |
31.5 |
-9.5 |
5.3 |
1.4 |
9.2 |
|
199.1 |
0.0 |
0112 |
2.7 |
1.5 |
52.8 |
-4.0 |
6.0 |
6.3 |
50.1 |
|
10203.9 |
0.0 |
0201 |
5.1 |
2.5 |
65.4 |
-17.2 |
9.9 |
3.3 |
18.2 |
|
1184.5 |
0.0 |
0202 |
2.1 |
1.3 |
28.6 |
-5.9 |
4.9 |
3.2 |
16.9 |
|
1008.3 |
0.0 |
0203 |
1.5 |
1.1 |
18.4 |
-16.7 |
3.9 |
0.6 |
13.5 |
|
477.3 |
0.0 |
0204 |
2.1 |
1.0 |
26.3 |
-12.2 |
4.8 |
2.1 |
11.9 |
|
417.4 |
0.0 |
0205 |
1.5 |
0.8 |
20.4 |
-37.6 |
5.0 |
-3.9 |
39.9 |
|
6120.9 |
0.0 |
0206 |
1.1 |
1.1 |
11.8 |
-34.9 |
6.2 |
-3.7 |
21.6 |
|
1714.5 |
0.0 |
0207 |
1.7 |
1.5 |
17.0 |
-16.4 |
4.3 |
-0.4 |
8.4 |
|
128.5 |
0.0 |
0208 |
2.9 |
1.3 |
60.3 |
-18.8 |
8.3 |
5.1 |
34.6 |
|
4725.7 |
0.0 |
0209 |
3.8 |
2.2 |
45.6 |
0.0 |
6.5 |
4.3 |
24.3 |
|
2272.6 |
0.0 |
0210 |
2.7 |
1.3 |
31.9 |
-5.8 |
4.8 |
3.1 |
16.7 |
|
980.1 |
0.0 |
0211 |
2.4 |
1.3 |
29.2 |
-4.8 |
4.0 |
3.6 |
21.8 |
|
1732.8 |
0.0 |
0212 |
1.4 |
0.9 |
16.7 |
-6.0 |
2.6 |
2.4 |
13.9 |
|
608.3 |
0.0 |
APPENDIX 2:
UNIT ROOT TESTS
In order to be able to interpret the results of the OLS
regressions presented in Section IV correctly, we need to investigate the time
series properties of the series used in our regressions, i.e by carrying out
unit-root tests. Looking for the
presence of unit-root in various relative price variability measures, i.e
VR103(mom), VR103(yoy), VR10(mom), VR10(yoy) would also provide information
about whether the effect of shocks to the variability measures would dissappear
over time or approach a nonzero permanent level.
In testing for the presence of a unit-root in various
relative price variability measures and variables related to inflation, we make
use of the Augmented Dickey-Fuller (ADF) test. Suspecting (from the plot of the
data) that the series in question may have one or more outliers, we test for
the presence of additive outliers (AO) using the methodology developed by
Vogelsang (1999) and carry out the ADF tests also by introducing the additive
outliers in the regression equation in the manner suggested by Franses and
Haldrup (1994)[1].
Table A.2.1: Results of
Outlier Detection Test Results |
|||||||||||||||||||||||
|
tc |
Outlier |
|||||||||||||||||||||
vr103(mom) |
8.936** |
1994:04 |
|||||||||||||||||||||
vr103(yoy) |
4.686** |
2002:01 |
|||||||||||||||||||||
|
5.401** |
2002:02 |
|||||||||||||||||||||
vr10(mom) |
6.372** |
1995:09 |
|||||||||||||||||||||
|
5.496** |
1994:04 |
|||||||||||||||||||||
|
5.264** |
1998:08 |
|||||||||||||||||||||
vr10(yoy) |
3.307** |
1999:11 |
|||||||||||||||||||||
|
3.515** |
1999:01 |
|||||||||||||||||||||
|
9.014** |
1994:04 |
|||||||||||||||||||||
|
2.624 |
1995.01 |
|||||||||||||||||||||
|
14.260** |
1994:04 |
|||||||||||||||||||||
|
4.869** |
2001:04 |
|||||||||||||||||||||
|
4.575** |
2001:03 |
|||||||||||||||||||||
|
3.29** |
2001:04 |
|||||||||||||||||||||
Notes: The critical values for the tc are taken from the Table 1 of Erlat (2002). Asymptotic
Critical Values for the tc Test:
*:significant at
the 10% level. **: significant at the 5% level |
In Table A.4.1 the results of the outlier detection
procedure of Vogelsang (1999) is shown[2]. For all of the series
measured on a month over month basis (except for
Having detected the significant outliers in the series of
interest, we go on with ADF tests (Table A.4.2). We include the additive
outliers to the test equation in such a way that the distribution of the
asymptotic null distribution of the t-statistics are not changed (Erlat,2002).
For this end, each outlier is included in the regression with the appropriate
lag length, i.e supposing that the ADF test equation involves 3 lags of the
dependent variable, each outlier appears with three lags in the regression.
Thus, if there are 2 outliers, there would be 6 dummy variables. As stated in
Erlat (2002), the inclusion of the additive outliers in the above-mentioned
manner may be problematic especially if the outliers are close to the beginning
of the sample or if there are adjacent outliers. In such cases, the equation
cannot be estimated because of perfect multicollinearity.
Table A.2.2: ADF Test
Results With and Without Impulse Dummies |
|||||||||||||||||||||||
|
T |
P |
ADF |
LB(24) |
Dummies |
||||||||||||||||||
Without
Dummies |
|
|
|
|
|
||||||||||||||||||
vr103(mom) |
105 |
0 |
-9.243** |
8.189
(0.999) |
|
||||||||||||||||||
vr103(yoy) |
94 |
1 |
-3.607** |
11.178 (0.988) |
|
||||||||||||||||||
vr10(mom) |
105 |
0 |
-10.478** |
26.852 (0.311) |
|
||||||||||||||||||
vr10(yoy) |
94 |
1 |
-3.147** |
15.668 (0.900) |
|
||||||||||||||||||
|
105 |
0 |
-6.449** |
26.923 (0.308) |
|
||||||||||||||||||
|
94 |
1 |
-2.030 |
16.117 (0.884) |
|
||||||||||||||||||
|
105 |
0 |
-7.121** |
4.732 (1.000) |
|
||||||||||||||||||
|
89 |
6 |
-4.821** |
22.25 (0.564) |
|
||||||||||||||||||
With
Dummies |
|
|
|
|
|
||||||||||||||||||
vr103(mom) |
105 |
0 |
-12.172** |
34.409 (0.078) |
d9404 |
||||||||||||||||||
vr103(yoy) |
94 |
1 |
-5.252** |
27.702 (0.273) |
d0201 |
||||||||||||||||||
vr10(mom) |
105 |
0 |
-14.845** |
27.753 (0.271) |
d9509,
d9404, d9808 |
||||||||||||||||||
vr10(yoy) |
94 |
1 |
-2.824 |
16.659 (0.863) |
d9911,
d9901 |
||||||||||||||||||
|
105 |
0 |
-9.643** |
55.232 (0) |
d9404 |
||||||||||||||||||
|
94 |
1 |
n.a |
n.a |
None |
||||||||||||||||||
|
105 |
1 |
-6.241 |
18.913 (0.757) |
d9404,d0104 |
||||||||||||||||||
|
89 |
6 |
-3.672 |
22.24 (0.565) |
d0104 |
||||||||||||||||||
Notes: LB stands for
the Ljung-Box statistic which has an asymptotic chi-square distribution with
k-p degrees of freedom under the null hypothesis, with k number of
autocorrelations. In this case, k=24 Due to Franses
and Haldrup (1994) the MacKinnon critical values (with constant) are
used.
|
Following Erlat (2002) the lag length is chosen in the
following manner: First of all, the choice of lag length is made without
accounting for the existence of the outliers. In choosing the lag length,
essentially three kinds of information are used: Akakie Information Criterion
(AIC), the Schwartz Information Criterion (SIC) and the sequential testing of
the coefficient of the last lag. If two of these comply with each other, the
corresponding lag length is chosen, if there is no compliance among them, the
choice is made according to the one that gives the highest lag length. The most
important criteria in the lag choice is the lack of autocorrelation in the
residuals. Thus if there is autocorrelation in the residuals despite agreement
among all the other criteria, we increase the lag length until we get rid of
autocorrelation[3].
The results of the ADF tests with and without impulse
dummies are shown in Table 2. The ADF tests without dummies imply that
only annual CPI inflation has a unit root. The null hypothesis of a unit root
is strongly rejected especially for the month over month relative price
variability measures. When we include impulse dummies to account for the
presence of additive outliers, the rejection is even more stronger for
VR103(mom), VR103(yoy) and VR10(mom). On the other hand, the unit root
hypothesis cannot be rejected for VR10(yoy) when the impulse dummies are added
to test equation. The rejection of a
unit root for the monthly inflation rate seems to be stronger when the April
1994 dummy is added to the test equation, but this ADF statistic cannot be
interpreted because there is autocorrelation in the residuals. In this
particular case, when the lag length is increased to get rid of autocorrelation
say to 2, the test equation cannot be estimated because the second lag of D9404
is a zero vector. Thus, we have to rely on the implication of the standard ADF
statistic for this variable, which
suggests that there is no unit root in the monthly inflation rate. This is also
valid for the case of annual inflation rate, since no significant outliers were
found using the outlier detection methodology described above.
[1] This
methodology was applied by Erlat (2002) for the
Turkish inflation series between January 1987-January 2000.
[2] For the details of the outlier detection procedure see Vogelsang (1999) and Erlat
(2002). The computer program used in outlier detection is the one written by Haluk Erlat in Shazam.
[3] In the lag length procedure, first a maximal lag length is chosen (13 in our case). Then, AIC and SIC are calculated dropping one lag at a time but keeping the sample size constant for the information criteria to be comparable. Testing for autocorrelation is done by using Ljung-Box statistic. The computer program which is originally written by Prof. Dr. Haluk Erlat in Shazam, is modified for this specific case.