OIL AND THE RENTIER STATE:
IRAN’S CAPITAL FORMATION, 1960-1997 ¹
Sousan Badiei and Cyrus Bina
California State Polytechnic University, Pomona and
University of Minnesota, Morris
binac@mrs.umn.edu
Keywords: Oil, Iran,
Capital Formation, Rentier State
JEL:O11, N5, Q4
1. INTRODUCTION
The focus of this study is on the “rentier” character
of state and economy in relation to capital accumulation during
the period of 1960-1997 in Iran. The rentier character and structure
of the Iranian State reflects the domination of the economy by the
oil sector (Mahdavy 1970, Bina 1992a). The rentier nature of the
Iranian economy is also potentially recognized through a strand
of literature in economic development, known as Dutch Disease (Katouzian
1978, Corden and Neary 1982, Corden 1984, Romer 1985, Evans 1986).
Such domination has continually been the common denominator of both
the Shah’s, as well as the Islamic Republic’s regimes
in Iran. For the analysis of oil rents theory, see Bina 1985 (Ch.
5), 1989, 1990, 1992b. It is shown through a simple but decisive
econometric model that oil revenues had a positive and significant
relationship with the long-term trend of gross fixed domestic capital
formation (GFDCF) during the latter part of Shah’s regime
in Iran. However, it is also shown that such a positive and significant
relationship had suddenly become negative after the legendary
oil price hike of 1973-1974, despite the fact that it brought an
enormous windfall to the Shah’s treasury by 1975 (Bina 1985,
1988, 1990, Karshenas 1990). The situation under the Islamic regime
has been somewhat different. Iran’s oil revenues have declined
substantially, and were subject to much fluctuation during the period
of 1980-1997 (Fesharaki 1985, Bina 1992a, EIU, various issues).
It is shown that econometrically there is no significant relationship
between the extent of oil revenues and the gross fixed domestic
capital formation (GFDCF) during the period of 1980-1997 in Iran.
Moreover, the Islamic regime in Iran does not appear to have paid
much attention to capital accumulation and long-term investment.
Instead, the government seems to have allocated the revenues from
oil rents to politically motivated consumption expenditures and
unproductive activities, presumably, to contain and ameliorate the
potential internal political upheavals and external threats during
the period under study (Mofid 1990, Yaghmaian 1992). The analogue
of these activities is the fact that the Government of the Islamic
Republic has consistently engaged in the allocation of various sorts
of (formal and informal) subsidies to those areas and interest groups
that provided sustained ideological and material support for the
fortification of the regime in Iran (see Bina and Zangeneh 1992,
Amuzegar 1993, Bina 1994a, 1999, Zangeneh 1997, 1999).
|
2. THE HYPOTHESES, MODEL, AND DATA
2.1. The
Hypotheses
Given the weight of the literature concerning the dominant nature
of oil revenues (rents) in the Iranian economy, the relationship
between the level of oil revenues and that of the gross fixed capital
formation is hypothesized as follows for different time periods:
Null Hypothesis I:
There is a significant relationship between
the amount of oil revenues and the level of gross fixed capital
formation (GFDCF) in the Iranian economy under the Shah’s
regime. There can be two outcomes, Ia and
Ib
Null Hypothesis Ia: There
is a positive (upward) shift in the above relationship (i.e., Null
Hypothesis I) since the 1973-oil crisis during the Shah’s
regime.
Alternative Hypothesis Ib:
There is a negative (downward) shift in the above relationship (i.e.,
null hypothesis I) since the 1973-oil crisis during the Shah’s
regime.
Alternative Hypothesis I
There is no relationship between the amount of oil revenues and
the level of gross fixed domestic capital formation in the Iranian
economy under the Shah’s regime.
Null Hypothesis II: There is a positive relationship between
the amount of oil revenues and the level of gross fixed domestic
capital formation (GFDCF) under the Islamic Republic in Iran.
Alternate Hypothesis II: There is no relationship between
the amount of oil revenues and the level of gross fixed capital
formation under the Islamic Republic in Iran.
These relationships are measured through the
test of significance of the corresponding linear models indicated
above. This would capture the hypothesized influence of oil revenues
on capital investment during the two sub-periods under study in
Iran. |
2.2. The Model
The entire period of the study extends from 1960 through 1997,
spanning the Shah’s regime as well as the IslamicRepublic
regime in Iran. This period is divided into the two sub-periods
of 1960-1979 and 1980-1997, corresponding with the above respective
regimes. The period under study is limited to the availability of
the time series data for the variables utilized in the model.
The model in its functional form is as follows:
It = (Rt),
where, correspondingly, Rt
and It stand for time
series of oil revenue (oil rent) and gross fixed capital formation,
assuming that It
is a linear function of Rt.Given
the structural differences between the Shah’s regime and the
regime of Islamic Republic, the entire period of 1960-1997 has been
divided into two sub-periods, each of which relates to the appropriate
regime. The models utilized in the estimation of parameters for
the two sub-periods are as follows:
(1) It =
a
+ bRt
+ Dt + e,
(2) I't = a'
+ b'R't
+ e',
where It and I't are designated as dependent
variables in time t, and Rt and
R't as independent variables for
oil revenues (oil rents) for the two sub-periods; a,
a',
b, and b'
are vectors of parameters in the equations (a
and a'
constants, and b
and b'
coefficients of independent variable), and e,
and e'
are the residuals, and D is a binary variable (see Pindyck and Rubinfeld
1998a, Kennedy 1998).
|
2.3. The Data
The time series data on the gross fixed domestic capital
formation (GFDCF) for the entire period of 1960-1997 are obtained
from the Central Bank of Iran (Bank Markazi, Annual Report,
various issues, EIU, various issues, IMF, International Financial
Statistics). These data are nominal and kept in Iranian
currency. As a result, one of the shortcomings of the data is the
lack of adjustment for inflation. However, while it would have been
desirable to utilize a real trend for a more accurate year-to-year
comparison, due to the lack of information on the actual inflation
rate in Iran, the authors had no choice except to utilize what was
available. The time series data on Iranian oil revenues is in US
dollars. Although problematic in terms of exchange rate, the
revenue has been converted to Iranian rials for both
sub-periods. These data are obtained from OPEC (Annual
Statistical Bulletin, various issues). The conversion of
the oil revenue data for the sub-period of 1960-1979 has been made
at 760 rials per US dollar. This rate was consistently
utilized by the Central Bank under the Shah (Pesaran 1992, Bina
1994b, EIU, various issues).
However, due to the unprecedented and unusual controls by the
Islamic Republic—particularly the policy of holding multiple
exchange rates—the oil revenue data for the period of 1979-1997 are
kept in its original (US dollar) denomination. Despite these
shortcomings, the time series are rather up-to-date and complete
relative to what had been available previously on Iran’s economy
(Bank Markazi 1998). |
|
Figure 1 shows the trend of the gross fixed domestic capital formation
(GFDCF) for the period of 1960-1997 in Iran. This trend reflects
the growth of the Iranian economy in the long run, and overlaps
the two regimes. While the shape of GFDCF somewhat resembles an
inverted "V" during the 1960-1979 period, it is nearly "N"-shaped
during the 1980-1997 period. GFDCF figures include gross capital
investment in agriculture, oil and gas, mining and manufacturing,
commercial and residential structures, and services. During the
Shah's regime, in the period under study, GFDCF has increased steadily-except
in the mid-1960s-through mid-1974, and then exhibited its sharpest
increase ever in the Iranian economy during the 1974-1975 period.
This period coincides, with a small lag, with the oil crisis of
early 1970s, and the worldwide oil price hike of 1973-1974 (Bina
1985, 1990). However, GFDCF declines sharply from 1976 through 1979,
when the Shah's regime was overthrown.
The trend of GDFCF during the regime of Islamic Republic is similarly
moving with the trend of Iran's oil revenues. Even though the trend
of GFDCF shows a brief decline, the new regime benefited from a
sharp increase in the global oil prices in 1986, and reversed its
direction. As can be seen from Figure 1, GDFCF shows a sharp increase
from 1981-1983 when it levels off first and begins to taper off
intensely from 1984 to 1987, a period of precipitous decline in
the oil prices. The period of 1987-1995, however, can be divided
into the two periods of sharp and (subsequent) moderate increase,
which levels off thereafter during the period under study (see Figure
1).
As for the oil revenues in Iran, given the Iranian Revolution (1979),
the period under study has been divided into the two sub-periods
of 1960-1979 and 1980-1997. As can be seen from the comparison of
the corresponding trends of oil revenues during the Shah's period,
they are nearly mirror image of each other in both US dollars and
Iranian rials (see Figures 2 and 3). This similarity stems from
the fact that the Iranian currency has remained stable vis-à-vis
the US dollar during this period. The oil revenues were steadily
increasing from 1960 through 1972, before showing a tremendous increase
during the oil crisis of 1973-1974, which has led to fourfold increase
of 'posted prices' by OPEC (Alnasrawi 1985, Bina 1985, 1988, 1990).
For the remainder of the period, however, oil revenues declined
moderately in 1974-1975, before another increase during the 1976-1977
period, followed by a sharp decline the final years of the Shah's
regime.
|
|
 |
The trend of the oil revenues during the reign of the Islamic Republic
is completely different from that of the Shah’s. The
oil revenues trend in terms of US dollars, as opposed to Iranian
rials, shows a marked difference. This difference is due to the
fact that data on the oil revenues are primarily collected by OPEC
in dollar terms and any conversion to rials must be made based upon
the declining value of the Iranian rial (vis-à-vis the US dollar)
during the period of 1980-1997. However, given the inconsistent
exchange-rate policies by the state since 1993, such a conversion
remains problematic. The problem is compounded by the fact that
the government of the Islamic Republic allowed the conversion according
to both the "official" and market-determined rates (Pesaran
1992, Bina 1990, 1992a, 1994b). Finally, due to severe domestic
inflation, any attempt at the conversion of oil revenues from US
dollars to Iranian rials would lead to an enormously inflated trend,
particularly since 1993. Nevertheless, as we shall see in
the estimations, an attempt has been made to utilize both converted
and dollar figures; the results are nearly the same.
As Figure 4 shows, there is an increase in the oil revenues from
1981 through 1983, following the revolution. However, there is
a sharp decline in that trend (in US dollars) from 1983 to 1986,
where the oil revenues reached their lowest level during this
sub-period. The decline of the converted oil revenue trend (in
Iranian rials), although more moderate by comparison, attains its
lowest level as well in 1986 (see Figure 5). In terms of US
dollars, oil revenues bottom out from the 1986 through 1990, and
level off thereafter toward the end of the period under study. Yet,
the trend of oil revenues since 1993, in terms of the official
devaluation of rial, shows a marked increase from 1986 through 1996,
and thereafter levels off toward the end of the period. The
difference between these two trends is due to the inevitable
devaluation of rial, which in turn reflects the existence of
domestic hyperinflation.
|
 |
 |
It is important to also look at the corresponding
trends of GDP and GDP growth during the 1960-1997 period
corresponding with the two regimes. Figure 6 shows GDP figures
in rial for the entire period under study. During the
1960-1976 period Iranian GDP shows a steady growth rate, with a
somewhat higher rate in the last two years, having, presumably, to
do with latent effect of the oil price hike. However, from
1976 through the end of the Shah’s regime in 1979, there is a sharp
decline in GDP as well as GFPCF (see Figures 6, 7 and 8). In
addition to the unmistakable effect of the revolutionary upheaval at
this time, there is a decline in the oil revenues as well (see
Figures 2 and 3). The economy, being at standstill due to the
revolutionary disruption at the beginning of the second sub-period,
then recovers sharply from 1980 through 1982, followed by an equally
sharp decline, hitting the bottom in 1986 (see Figures 6 and
7). The mirror image of this up-and-down, which is
apparent from the trend of GDP growth, can also be seen in the
up-and-down of the oil revenues—in terms of the stable US dollar
rather than hyperinflationary Iranian rial—during the 1980-1986
period (see Figures 4 and 5). From 1986 to 1990 the GDP
sharply increases—during the time when the oil revenues also
increase—followed by a moderate increase thereafter (see Pesaran
1992, Bina 1992a, Amuzegar 1993).
|
 |
 |
In the meantime, by looking at the trend of gross fixed public
capital formation (GFPCF) for the entire period of 1960-1997, nearly
the mirror image of the oil revenue trend comes to mind (see Figures
2, 4 and 8). This can be seen as a clear indication that
Iran’s economy possesses a rentier character, which, by and large,
depends upon the exportation of oil alone (Bina 1992a, Zangeneh
1997). In the next section, we shall demonstrate this point
more systematically. |
 |
Finally, GFDCF trend as the percentage of GDP for the entire
period under study is yet another indicator of the centrality of oil
in the Iranian economy. Moreover, this trend nearly mimics the
oil revenue trend for the sub-period of 1960-1980 (see Figures 2 and
9). The GFDCF trend as the percentage of GDP for the
sub-period of 1980-1997, however, is not as similar as the oil
revenue trend in comparison with their counterparts during the
sub-period of 1960-1979. Yet, the two trends are somewhat
moving in the same direction perhaps with a year or two lagged
periods (see Figures 4 and 11). |
 |
 |
 |
3. THE EMPIRICAL FINDINGS
Given the instability of the Iranian rial in terms of the US
dollar during the Islamic Republic (1980-1997), and the desire to
measure in similar framework the relationships in the models, the
estimation has been done with oil revenues in both US dollars and
Iranian rials (Pesaran 1992, Bina 1994b). As can be seen from
the estimation of Equation Ia and Equation Ib
(Tables 1 & 2), this distinction is not consequential for
the Shah’s regime. The OLS (Ordinary Least Squares) method has
been employed via Eviews (version 4) in this study. The
estimated coefficient of oil revenues for the sub-period of
1960-1979 is significant (and positive) at 1% level while the
coefficient of constant in the equation shows no statistical
significance.
At the same time, by employing the dummy variable technique in
the latter period (See Table 1), we attempt to find out that whether
there has been a significant shift in the function. In this
manner, the period of 1960-1979 has been divided into the two
sub-periods of 1960-1973 and 1974-1979, corresponding with 0 and 1,
measuring the impact of the oil crisis. The coefficient for
Dt is at the 1% significance level. However, the
sign is negative indicating that the quadrupled OPEC oil “posted
prices” in 1974, and thus the effect of substantial increase in the
oil revenues had indeed been negative for capital investment
in Iran during the Shah’s regime. In other words, peculiarly
enough, increased oil revenues corresponded with a substantial
reduction in the amount of capital formation in the latter part of
the Shah’s regime.
This result may seem somewhat anomalous upon initial inspection.
However, this finding does not appear out of ordinary when it is
subjected to a closer examination, particularly by focusing on the
Shah’s monumental military expenditures in the latter part
of 1970s. The above result is also supported by the so-called
Dutch Disease literature, associated with traditional development
economics, in which the booming production of a single commodity
(i.e., raw material) would ordinarily lead to deindustrialization
of the economy as a whole (see Katouzian 1978, Corden and Neary
1982, Corden 1984, Romer 1985, Evans 1986). The goodness of
fit of the estimation, measured by R-squared, is 0.93%, with no
serial correlation (see the D.W. statistic in the appropriate table
below) in the regression equation.
Given the suspicion that economic-series often exhibit non-stationary
attributes, the augmented Dickey-Fuller (ADF) test was conducted
on I (GFDCF) and R (OILD, OIL). OILD stands for oil
revenues in U.S. dollars and OIL represents revenues in Iranian
rials. The sample was divided into two sample study periods
of 1960-1979 and 1980-1997. For the first sample period, the
respective t-values of the ADF test for I and R were –1.13
and – 2.13; indicating that both series were non-stationary.
However, a co-integration test for the regression equation (i.e.,
the statistical relationship of I, R, and D)
shows that the model is co-integrated. The t-value of the
unit root test for the residual of the regression equation is –2.47,
in conjunction with MacKinnon 5% critical value of –1.96.
The unit root test for the sample period of 1980-1997 showed again
that both I and R were non-stationary series at the
99% significance level. However, our model was co-integrated
at the 95% significance level. The t-value unit root for the regression
equation is –2.23, with the MacKinnon 5% critical value 1.96.
Therefore, our unit root test confirms the stationarity of the model,
and validity of our estimated coefficients for both equations associated
with both periods under study (see Greene 2000, Ch. 18).
|
TABLE 1
Result of Equation Ia:
1960-1979:
Shah’s Era and First Oil Crisis, Oil Revenues in US
Dollars
Dependent Variable: I |
Method: Least Squares |
|
Sample: 1960-1979 |
Included observations: 20 |
Variable |
Coefficient |
Std.
Error |
t-Statistic |
Prob. |
C |
155.9192 |
99.67088 |
1.564341 |
0.1362 |
OILD |
0.265182 |
0.038575 |
6.874456 |
0.0000 |
D |
-3295.808 |
758.6805 |
-4.344131 |
0.0004 |
R-squared |
0.941972 |
Mean dependent
var |
1218.280 |
Adjusted R-squared |
0.935145 |
S.D. dependent
var |
985.1633 |
S.E. of regression |
250.8880 |
Akaike info criterion |
14.02537 |
Sum squared resid |
1070062. |
Schwarz
criterion |
14.17473 |
Log likelihood |
-137.2537 |
F-statistic |
137.9806 |
Durbin-Watson stat |
1.808420 |
Prob(F-statistic) |
0.000000 | |
Finally, the regression equation with converted oil revenues into
rial would also show the same result (Table 2). This indicates a
statistically significant coefficient (at the 1% level) for oil
revenue, with positive sign as well as similar significance (at
the 1% level) for Dt with a negative sign (see the results
for Equation Ia and Equation Ib below).
As a result, we accept null hypothesis I. Moreover,
we confirm that there is a significant statistical relationship
between the vector of oil revenues and capital investments during
the sub-period of 1960-1979 in Iran. This relationship is
positive, as the sign of the coefficient of oil revenues would indicate
(see Pindyck and Rubinfeld 1998a, 1998b, Kennedy 1998).
Finally, we reject null hypothesis Ia and accept
alternative hypothesis Ib. This confirms the fact that
there is a significant downward shift in the coefficient of
constant, having to do with the oil windfall of the 1974 in
Iran. The result is consistent with Dutch Disease
literature as well, having to do with the negative effect of
reliance on a single commodity in the process of economic
development. |
TABLE 2
Result of Equation Ib:
1960-1979:
Shah’s Era and First Oil Crisis, Oil Revenues in
Iranian Rial
Dependent Variable: I |
Method: Least Squares |
|
Sample: 1960-1979 |
Included observations: 20 |
Variable |
Coefficient |
Std. Error |
t-Statistic |
Prob. |
C |
156.5321 |
99.56148 |
1.572215 |
0.1343 |
OIL |
0.348811 |
0.050715 |
6.877866 |
0.0000 |
D |
-3294.588 |
758.1319 |
-4.345665 |
0.0004 |
R-squared |
0.942014 |
Mean dependent var |
1218.280 |
Adjusted R-squared |
0.935192 |
S.D. dependent var |
985.1633 |
S.E. of regression |
250.7966 |
Akaike info criterion |
14.02464 |
Sum squared resid |
1069281. |
Schwarz criterion |
14.17400 |
Log likelihood |
-137.2464 |
F-statistic |
138.0875 |
Durbin-Watson stat |
1.807775 |
Prob(F-statistic) |
0.000000 | |
|
|
The regression equations for the sub-period of 1980-1997 are similarly
testing the relationship of the oil revenue and capitalinvestment
trends under the Islamic Republic in Iran (Table 3 & 4). In
Equation IIa, oil revenues are in U.S. dollars while
gross fixed domestic capital formation (GFDCF) is in Iranian rials.
For easier interpretation of the coefficients in Equation IIb,
oil revenues are converted to the same unit as the GFDCF, Iranian
rials. Given the instability of foreign exchange, and the
existence of parallel markets in foreign currency in Iran, however,
such a conversion is by no means immune from controversy.
In the estimation of both Equation IIa and Equation
IIb, we encountered the problem of serial correlation.
After solving for significant second-order serial correlation associated
with both of these regression equations, we have obtained no significant
statistical relationship between the vector of oil revenues and
that of capital investments during the period of 1980-1997 in Iran.
Moreover, the coefficient of oil revenues in both regression equations
is not significantly different from zero. Consequently, we
reject null hypothesis II and accept alternative hypothesis
II associated with the sub-period of 1980-1997. In other words,
we confirm that there is no (statistically) significant relationship
between oil revenues and capital investments during the Islamic
Republic in Iran. Given the dismal conditions of the Iranian
economy, not only did oil revenues decline, but they also were not
properly allocated to productive investments that were essential
for the economic growth during the period of 1980-1997. Moreover,
the Islamic Republic appears to have allocated the oil revenues
toward consumption, thus neutralizing the external threat and, more
importantly, subsidizing the domestic interest groups whose ideological
support has been essential for the preservation of regime in Iran.
Figures 12 (U.S. dollars) and 13 (Iranian rials) plot the goodness
of fit for the actual and predicted trends of GDFCF for the first
sub-period 1960-1979. Figures 14 (U.S. dollars) and 15 (Iranian
rials) give the same information for the second sub-period 1980-1997.
Visual examination of the goodness of fit, notwithstanding the above
tests, shows us that the estimated models are valid.
|
TABLE 3
Result of Equation IIa:
1980-1997:
(Oil Revenues in US Dollars)
Dependent Variable: I |
Method: Least Squares |
|
Sample: 1980-1997 |
Included observations: 18 |
Convergence achieved after 13
iterations |
Variable |
Coefficient |
Std. Error |
t-Statistic |
Prob. |
C |
2082.350 |
319.9946 |
6.507454 |
0.0000 |
OILD |
-0.003835 |
0.017673 |
-0.217001 |
0.8313 |
AR(1) |
1.143687 |
0.197952 |
5.777587 |
0.0000 |
AR(2) |
-0.468628 |
0.194958 |
-2.403731 |
0.0306 |
R-squared |
0.718400 |
Mean dependent var |
1942.267 |
Adjusted R-squared |
0.658058 |
S.D. dependent var |
455.2998 |
S.E. of regression |
266.2404 |
Akaike info criterion |
14.19981 |
Sum squared resid |
992375.1 |
Schwarz criterion |
14.39767 |
Log likelihood |
-123.7983 |
F-statistic |
11.90533 |
Durbin-Watson stat |
1.687197 |
Prob(F-statistic) |
0.000383 |
|
TABLE 4
Result of Equation IIb:
1980-1997:
(Oil Revenues in Iranian Rials)
Dependent Variable: I |
Method: Least Squares |
|
Sample: 1980-1997 |
Included observations: 18 |
Convergence achieved after 11
iterations |
|
Variable |
Coefficient |
Std. Error |
t-Statistic |
Prob. |
C |
1859.563 |
290.9086 |
6.392259 |
0.0000 |
OIL |
0.009356 |
0.014073 |
0.664837 |
0.5170 |
AR(1) |
1.032612 |
0.217171 |
4.754841 |
0.0003 |
AR(2) |
-0.398013 |
0.203277 |
-1.957982 |
0.0705 |
R-squared |
0.722656 |
Mean dependent var |
1942.267 |
Adjusted R-squared |
0.663225 |
S.D. dependent var |
455.2998 |
S.E. of regression |
264.2210 |
Akaike info criterion |
14.18458 |
Sum squared resid |
977378.5 |
Schwarz criterion |
14.38244 |
Log likelihood |
-123.6612 |
F-statistic |
12.15960 |
Durbin-Watson stat |
1.674789 |
Prob(F-statistic) |
0.000345 |
|
 |
|
4. CONCLUSIONS
This study reveals the essential characteristics of an economy
that is dependent on the collection of economic rent associated with
the production of a single commodity, namely, oil. The
rentier in Iran’s case is the state itself (thus, rentier
state), and oil is a single commodity whose price has been
forcefully determined by the globalized oil market since the
1970s. The subject under study also has a counterpart in the
economic development literature, known as Dutch Disease, which
pertains to the effect of the booming raw material sector on
deindustrialization of the economy as a whole. In this manner,
both of these approaches lead to similar conclusions that the undo
domination of one particular sector, if not countered by appropriate
policy, would ultimately lead to “deindustrilization” of the economy
as a whole. The rentier characteristic is particularly
relevant to many oil-producing states in the Middle East.
We have demonstrated that the Iranian economy has long been
dominated by the oil sector, and by the global oil market. The
oil exports have a lion share of Iran’s international trade, and the
oil revenues constitute the main source of country’s foreign
exchange earnings. The entire period of 1960-1997 is divided
into the two sub-periods of 1960-1979 and 1980-1997, corresponding
with the Shah’s and the Islamic Republic regimes,
respectively. During the Shah’s regime, the trend of capital
formation (a vital source of economic growth) shows a positive and
significant relationship with the volume of Iranian oil
revenues. However, following the oil-price hike of mid-1970s,
which brought a monumental windfall to the Shah’s treasury, the oil
revenues have had a negative effect on the capital formation
in Iran. From the standpoint of economic development, therefore,
this is clearly evidence of outright waste (e.g., conspicuous
consumption and monumental military expenditure), and neglectful
economic conduct on the part of Iranian government under the
Shah.
As for the oil policy and economic development under the Islamic
government, the trend of oil revenues shows no significant
relationship with that of Iran’s national capital formation.
It is true that Iran’s oil export capacity has been reduced
considerably under the Islamic government. It is also true
that the global oil prices have been on a declining trend, thus
resulting in declining oil revenues (and foreign exchange) for Iran
during the last two decades or so.
Yet, the question of Iran-Iraq war aside, it is important to note
that the Islamic government has completely neglected the task of
capital formation, and instead pursued, perhaps deliberately, a
myopic policy of attending to (short-term) consumption expenditures
(see The Third Five-Year Development Plan, 1999-2004).
Such an economic policy may have been motivated by the threat of
potential (domestic) social and political upheavals, thus revealing
the diehard tendency of extending state subsidies to certain social
strata, interest groups and institutions that have provided
protection and ideological support to the present regime in Iran.
|
END NOTES
- This paper was presented at the Middle East Economic
Association / Allied Social Science Association Meeting, Jauary,
4-6, 2002, Atlanta, GA, USA
REFERENCES
Alnasrawi, Abbas,
OPEC in a Changing World Economy, Baltimore, Johns
Hopkins Press, 1985.
Amuzegar, Jahangir,
Iran’s Economy Under the Islamic Republic, New York and
London, I. B. Tauris, 1993.
Bank Markazi
Jomhuri-ye Eslami-ye Iran, Hesabha-ye Melli-ye Iran 1353-1376
[1974/1975-1996/1997] (Tehran: 1378).
Bank Markazi
Jomhuri-ye Eslami-ye Iran, Gozaresh-e Eqtesadi va Taraznameh
(Tehran: 1357 to 1369 [1978/79-1990/91]).
Bina, Cyrus, The
Economics of the Oil Crisis, New York, St. Martin’s Press,
1985.
Bina, Cyrus,
“Internationalization of the Oil Industry: Simple Oil Shocks or
Structural Crisis,” Review: Journal of Fernand Braudel
Center, Vol. 11 (3), Summer 1988, pp. 329-370.
Bina, Cyrus, “Some
Controversies in the Development of Rent Theory: The Nature of Oil
Rent,” Capital & Class, NO. 39, Winter 1989, pp.
82-112.
Bina, Cyrus, “Limits
of OPEC Pricing: OPEC Profits and the Nature of Global Oil
Accumulation,” OPEC Review, Vol. 14 (1), Spring 1990, pp.
55-73.
Bina, Cyrus, “Global
Oil and the Oil Policies of the Islamic Republic,” in C. Bina and H.
Zangeneh (eds.), Modern Capitalism and Islamic Ideology in Iran,
New York, St. Martin’s Press, 1992a, pp. 121-158.
Bina, Cyrus, “The
Laws of Economic Rent and Property: Applied to the Oil Industry,”
The American Journal of Economics & Sociology, Vol. 51
(2), April 1992b, pp. 187-203.
Bina, Cyrus, “Towards
a New World Order: U.S. Hegemony, Client States and Islamic
Alternative,” in H. Mutalib and T. Hashmi (eds.), Islam, Muslims
and the Modern State, London, Macmillan, 1994a, pp. 3-30.
Bina, Cyrus, “The
Foreign Exchange Crisis and the Fragility of the Iranian Economy,”
Mehregan, Vol.3 (4), Winter 1994b, pp. 117-131, (in Persian,
with English abstract).
Bina, Cyrus, “The Hot Summer of Defiance: The
Student Protests for Freedom and Democracy in Iran,” Journal of
Iranian Research and Analysis, Vol. 15, No. 2, November 1999,
pp. 47-62.
Bina, Cyrus, and H.
Zangeneh, Modern Capitalism and Islamic Ideology in Iran
(eds.), New York, St. Martin’s Press, 1992.
Corden, W. M.,
“Booming Economic Sector and Dutch Disease Economics: Survey and
Consolidation,” Oxford Economic Paper, Vol. 36, 1984, pp.
359-380.
Corden, W. M. and I.
Peter Neary, “Booming Sector and Deindustrialization in a Small Open
Economy,” Economic Journal, December 1982, pp. 825-848.
Economist
Intelligence Unit (EIU), Iran: Country Profile, London, 1993/94.
Economist
Intelligence Unit (EIU), Iran: Country Profile, London,
1995/1996.
Economist
Intelligence Unit (EIU), Iran: Country Profile, London,
1997/1998.
Evans, David,
“Reverse Dutch Disease and Mineral-Exporting Developing Economics,”
IDS Bulletin, Vol. 17 (October 1986), pp. 10-13.
Fesharaki, Fereidun,
“Iran’s Petroleum Policy: How does the Oil Industry Function in
Revolutionary Iran?” in Afshar, H. (ed.), A Revolution in
Turmoil, Albany, New York, SUNY Press, 1985, pp. 99-117.
Greene, William H.,
Econometric Analysis (4th Edition), Upper Saddle River,
New Jersey, Prentice Hall, 2000.
International
Monetary Fund, Direction of Trade Statistics (Washington,
D.C.: 1979 to 1992).
International
Monetary Fund, International Financial Statistics Yearbook
(Washington, D.C.: 1979 to 1995).
International
Monetary Fund, International Financial Statistics Yearbook
(Washington, D.C.: November 1993, December 1996, November 1998).
International
Monetary Fund, Government Finance Statistics Yearbook
(Washington: 1988 to 1998).
Islamic Republic of
Iran, A Statistical Reflection of the IRI, No. 4, Statistical
Center of Iran, no date.
Karshenas, Massoud,
Oil, State, and Industrialization in Iran Cambridge,
Cambridge University Press, 1990.
Katouzian, H., “Oil
versus Agriculture: a Case of Dual Resource Depletion in Iran,”
Journal of Peasant Studies, 1978, pp. 347-369.
Kennedy, Peter, A
Guide to Econometrics (4th Edition), Cambridge, MA,
The MIT Press, 1998.
Mahdavy, H., “The
Patterns and Problems of Economic Development in Rentier States: the
Case of Iran,” in Cook, M. A. (ed.), Studies in the Economic
History of the Middle East, London, Oxford University Press,
1970, pp. 37-61.
Markaz-e Amare-e
Iran, Salnameh-e Amari-ye Keshvar (Tehran: 1366 to 1370 [1987
to 1990]).
Ministry of
Petroleum, Annual Report, Tehran, Iran, various issues.
Mofid, Kamran, The
Economic Consequences of the Gulf War, London, Routledge,
1990.
OPEC, Annual
Statistical Bulletin, Vienna, Austria, various issues.
Pesaran, M. H., “The
Iranian Foreign Exchange Policy and the Black Market for Dollars,”
International Journal of Middle East Studies, February 1992,
pp. 113-127.
Pindyck, R. S. and D.
L. Rubinfeld, Econometric Models and Economic Forecasts
(4th Edition), New York, McGraw-Hill, 1998a.
Pindyck, R. S., and
D. L. Rubinfeld, Microeconomics (4th Edition),
Upper Saddle River, NJ, Prentice-Hall, 1998b.
Plan and Budget
Organization, The Third Five-Year Development Plan (1378-1383
[1999-2004]), Tehran, Iran, 1378.
Romer, Michael,
“Dutch Disease in Developing Countries: Swallowing Bitter Medicine,”
In Mats Lundahl (ed.), The Primary Sector in Economic
Development, New York, St. Martin’s, 1985, pp. 234-252.
Yaghmaian, Behzad,
“Recent Development in the Political Economy of Iran: The Triangle
Crisis,” in Bina and Zangeneh (eds.) Modern Capitalism and
Islamic Ideology in Iran, New York, St. Martin’s Press, 1992,
pp. 159-188.
Zangeneh, Hamid,
“Direction and Evolution of International Trade in Iran,”
Research in Middle East Economics, Vol. 2, 1997, pp.
165-191.
Zangeneh, Hamid,
“Economic Consequences of Student Unrest,” Journal of Iranian
Research and Analysis, Vol. 15, No. 2, November 1999, pp.
132-141. | |