DOES AN
EXCHANGE-RATE-BASED STABILIZATION PROGRAMME HELP FOR DISINFLATION IN TURKEY?
by
Öner Günçavdi
and Benan Zeki Orbay
Istanbul Technical University
email: oner@ayasofya.isl.itu.edu.tr, and benan@ayasofya.isl.itu.edu
Abstract
This paper examines the sensitivity of relative prices
in the Turkish manufacturing industry to fluctuations in exchange rates.
In our theoretical model, domestic and foreign firms produce substitutable
goods for the domestic market. Some portions of domestic firm’s inputs are
assumed to be imported. Results show that in the absence of imported input
usage in domestic production, relative domestic prices decreases after a devaluation
of domestic currency. However, if domestic industry imports some of its inputs
and the share of imported inputs in total domestic production cost is substantial,
relative domestic prices may increase with devaluation. The other variables
affecting the relative prices exchange rate relationship are degree of differentiation
of the products, the number of domestic and foreign firms in the market, size
of the market and the cost of foreign firms. Empricial results from Turkish
Manufacturing industry support most of our theoretical findings.
Key Words : exchange rate pass-through,
inflation, Turkey
In this study
the objective is to examine structural causes of the Turkish inflation.
In particular we aim to put a particular emphasis on the exchange rate
pass-through mechanism and the impacts of the market structure and the high
imported input dependence of Turkish manufacturing sector on this transmission
mechanism. There are considerable amount of studies in the literature in this
area. On the theoretical side, Dornbusch’s (1987) seminal paper is the leading
study in the literature. He investigates
the determinants and extent of exchange rate pass through under different
market structures. Using a Salop’s
type circular city differentiated product model, he indicates that relative
prices of domestic goods increase with the appreciation of domestic currency,
and the extent of this decrease is influenced by the degree of competition
and the relative number of domestic and foreign firms.
On the empirical side of the literature, most of the studies examine
the subject for developed and relatively large economies (e.g. Yang, 1997;
Menon, 1995; Athukorala and Menon, 1995; Feenstra, 1989; Feinberg, 1986, 1989,
1991). There has been less research on developing small economies (e.g. Günçavdi
and Orbay, 1998; Lee, 1997).
Our focus
in this study is on the Turkish economy. In order to analyze the effects of
exchange rate fluctuation on relative domestic prices, we set up a simple
theoretical model consisting two countries (one domestic and other foreign
country representing the rest of the world).
In accordance with the economic structure of the Turkish economy, we
assume that production in the domestic country has a certain imported input
component. It is also assumed that firms in the domestic country operate with a
less efficient technology than the foreign counterparts. In our differentiated product model domestic
and foreign firms determine their production levels simultaneously a la Cournot. The results show that with
sufficiently small imported input dependency, depreciation of domestic currency
leads to a decline in the ratio of domestic good prices to the price of
imported brands. However, high import dependency of domestic production may
change lead to a reverse relationship, i.e.
depreciation may increase the relative domestic good prices. Degree of
differentiation of the domestic and foreign products, the number of domestic
and foreign firms in the market, size of the market and the cost of foreign
firms are the other important variables affecting the direction and the
magnitude of the relationship between relative domestic prices and exchange
rates.
In the second part of our
study, we test the theoretical findings with the data from Turkish
economy. We use the past 114 years of
data (1982-1995) for each of 29 Turkish manufacturing industries, defined at 3
digit ISIC level. The empirical model includes the exchange
rate variable, and some other multiplicative terms of exchange rates with the
market structure variable, the share of imported inputs and a proxy for the
degree of differentiation of the products.
By doing so, we derive the responsiveness of relative domestic good
prices to exchange rates as a function of the industry specific factors. Results
show that as indicated in our model exchange rate fluctuations are important
determinants of the relative domestic price changes and the direction of this
relationship depends on the share of imported input usage. In particular,
devaluation of Turkish lira is among the culprits inflationary pressure on
relative domestic price in industries with high imported input dependency.
This paper is organized as
follows. Section 2 includes our theoretical model. Empirical results are
presented in Section 3. Concluding remarks are given in Section 4.
2. THE
THEORETICAL MODEL
The theoretical
model here is built upon our earlier models (see Günçavdi and Orbay, 2000).
In a two-country world (namely a developing home country and a developed
foreign country), the model assume that there are n
firms for a given industry in the developing home country, and n* firms in the developed foreign one. We also assume that the home country possesses
relatively inefficient production technologies and high import dependence
in production. For simplicity we
assume no transportation costs.
On the
supply side of the model, a typical firm i
in the home country operates under a Cobb-Douglas production technology with a
constant-returns-to-scale, and uses both domestic, ki, and imported, ki*,
inputs:
(1)
where xi is the output level of the ith firm, and s
is the share of imported inputs in
total costs. Using the production
function in equation (1), the indirect cost function accruing to the domestic
firm can be written as follows.
(2)
where , e is the
exchange rate and r, r*
are the unit costs of domestic and foreign inputs respectively. The firms in the foreign country are assumed
to use only their own domestic inputs and cost function of the ith foreign firm can be represented
in the following form.
,
where yi is the of output level of the foreign firm produced
for the developing country. As stated before, we assume that foreign firms
possess cost advantages over domestic ones mainly because they operate with
more efficient technology and encounter lower input prices. This assumption therefore implies that foreign
firms’ unit cost of production is lower than the unit cost of the domestic
firm; that is .
On
the demand side of the model, we assume linear demand functions for both types
of products, domestic and foreign, respectively as follows.
,
(4a)
, a, b, d >0
(4b)
where and
.
The values of b and d
respectively show the degree of differentiation of the domestic and imported goods. As b and d become closer, degree of differentiation
decreases. Profit functions of domestic
and foreign firms can, in turn, be written, respectively, as
(5a)
(5b)
We assume that firms compete a la Cournot. Thus, they choose their
quantities of production simultaneously.
In order to compute Cournot equilibrium outputs, first, we obtain the
reaction function of each firm from first-order conditions. Simultaneous solution of the reaction
functions yields the following equilibrium levels of outputs of domestic and
foreign firms,
( 6a)
(6b)
where .
Substituting (6) into (4) yields the equilibrium prices for the domestic
and foreign products, respectively, as follows.
(7a)
(7b)
where shows
degree of differentiation of domestic and foreign goods and
. The relative
domestic prices are
(8)
(9)
where and
(C is the unit cost of domestic firms). As stated in the previous section,
the exchange rate elasticity of prices is referred to exchange rate pass-through
in the related literature. Equation (9) indicates that the direction of the
exchange rate pass-through on relative domestic prices depends on the sign
of the term
. It is clear
that when s is zero
i.e.
in the case of no imported input usage the relative domestic prices will decrease
as a result of a depreciation of the domestic currency. This result is consistent
with the previous literature (see Dornbusch (1987)). However, when s is positive, then it is possible to observe a reverse relationship
between the relative domestic prices and exchange rates. More specifically,
when
is large, which is in fact the sum of the imported share of unit cost
of domestic firms, it is plausible to observe that
. It must
be noted here that sufficiently large
is
only a necessary condition, it is not sufficient. Sufficiency depends on the
magnitude of the other variables such as, degree of differentiation of the
products, (f), the size of the market (a), sum of the cost of foreign firms.
Having discussed the results of our theoretical model, the following
hypothesis can be arisen to test the importance of fluctuations in exchange
rates in the domestic price formation in Turkey.
H1: In the case of substantial
imported inputs usage in production, relative domestic good prices may increase
as a response to a depreciation of Turkish Lira against foreign currencies.
H2: Degree of differentiation of the
products, the number of domestic and foreign firms, size of the market and
the cost of foreign firms are important variables (in addition to the share
of imported input usage), affecting the direction and the magnitude of the
relationship between relative domestic prices and exchange rates.
In the following section, we will
test these expectations empirically for the Turkish manufacturing data.
3. AN
EMPIRICAL ANALYSIS
Having
presented theoretical discussion above, this section lays emphasis upon empirical testing of the link between movements in
foreign exchange (EXCH) and the
relative domestic price (RDP). Our aim is also to analyse the importance of
the industry-specific factors, in
particular, the imported input depenency that may influence the pass-through
mechanism between EXCH and RDP. Before
turning to the empirical testing, it must be noted the limitation of the data
in our sample. Following the theoretical discussion in the previous section,
testing the role of imported inputs in production on exchange rate passs-through
mechanism posses a crucial importance. The data from annual surveys of manufacturing industry in Turkey
contains no information on imported inputs in production at 3-digit disaggregation
level. Due to the lack of continuous
imported input data for the period of 1983-1993, we employ a simple procedure
to measure the import dependence of the domestic production of each industry
as follows. Using input-output tables
available for 1985 and 1990, we classified each industry according to its
dependence on imported inputs, and generate three different dummy variables,
namely D1, D2 and D3, each corresponding to the degree of
import dependence starting from low dependent industry and ending with high
dependent one. D1, D2 and D3 take the value
of unity for low dependent, dependent and high dependent industries respectively.
Following
the theoretical model in the previous section, we pay special attention on some
industry specific factors such as market structure, the degree of product
differentiation and the share of imported inputs in domestic production. Our aim is to see how the sensitivity of the
pass-through mechanism is affected by these factors, using the past 12 years of
the data (1982 to 1993) for each of 27 Turkish manufacturing industries,
defined at the 3-digit ISIC level.
Although the data is available for the period of 1980-1993, the sample
period in our empirical investigation corresponds to the liberalised exchange
rate period starting from 1982.
Herfindahl
Index, calculated by Günesş (1998), is chosen as a proxy variable to
capture the effects of market structure.
A measure of four-firm seller concentration ratio is also reported
in Günesş (1998), but its correlation with the Herfindahl Index is almost
0.97 (see Table 2). The real exchange
rate used in our empirical investigation is measured by the index of the trade
weighted real effective exchange rate of two important trade partners of Turkey,
namely the USA and Germany. In order
to capture the effects of general macroeconomic conditions, gross domestic
product (GDP), which may proxy to
some extent the demand condition in the economy, is included in the estimation
procedure. Following the empirical literature in intra-industry trade, a working
measure of the extent of intra-industry trade (IIT) is constructed as an index of trade overlap as follows.
(10)
where Xi and Mi
are the values of exports and imports in industry i, respectively. A higher
value of the index is posited to indicate a higher degree of product differentiation
in an industry. The definitions and
the sources of all variables are given in Table 1.
TABLE
1 : THE DEFINITION AND SOURCES OF VARIABLES
Variables |
|||
RDPit |
Source :
State Institute of Statistics (SIS). |
||
EXCHt |
Trade Weighted
Effective Real Exchange Rate Index, calculated from currency baskets
consisting of US Dollar and German Mark.
The weights in the basket for both currencies differ between
the periods of 1982-1986 and of
1987-1993. The weights for the former period are 0.5
for US Dollar and 0.5 for German mark whereas they are 0.75 for US Dollar
and 0.25 for German Mark in the second period. Source:
The Quarterly Bulletin of the Central Bank of Turkey. |
||
Mit |
The values of imports for
industry i, year t, Sources: State Institute of Statistics (SIS) |
||
|
|
||
Sij |
We
classified each industry according to its dependence on imported inputs
based on using input-output tables available for 1985 and 1990, and
generate three different dummy variables, namely D1,
D2 and D3, each corresponding
to the degree of import dependence starting from low dependent industry
and ending with high dependent one.
D1, D2 and D3 take the value of unity for low dependent, dependent and high
dependent industries respectively. |
||
|
Source: Günes, M. (1998),
Türk Imalat Sanayinde Yogunlasma Oranlarini Belirleyen Faktörler 1980-1994,
State Institue of Statistics, Ankara. |
||
|
|
||
The
empirical model is quite simple and follows Günçavdı and Orbay (1998), Lee
(1997) and Feinberg (1986, 1991). Pooled
cross-section/time-series data are used to estimate the exchange rate
elasticity of domestic prices and differences across industries in the
estimated elasticity are explained by industry-specific variables, intended to
proxy market structure (H), degree of
differentiation of products (IIT) and
the share of imported inputs in domestic production (S). We estimate the coefficients and standard
errors of the industry variables from interaction terms with the exchange rate.
Empirical supports for the hypothesis above are found out from the estimation
of following regressions on 336 pooled cross-section/time series observations (i=1,…,27; t=1982,…,1993) using the least square dummy variable (LSDV) method (see, Baltagi, 1995,
Green,1993; Hsiao, 1986,).
,
(11)
where small cases indicate
the logarithms of all relevant variables. Assuming that differences across
industries are fixed, equation (11) include a set of industry specific dummy variables. The effects of changes
in macroeconomic conditions are captured by the coefficient of gdp (a1),
which is kept constant across industries, and is expected to be positive. From
equation (11), exchange rate pass-through can be written as a function of these
industry specific factors by differentiating (11) with respect to the exchange
rate variable as follows.
(12)
where hi shows the
exchange rate pass-through for industry i
(i.e. the exchange rate elasticity of relative domestic prices). Equation (12) indicates that exchange rate
pass-through varies over time and across industries.
The results
of estimates are reported in Table 2. They show that one of the main determinant
of relative domestic price movements in Turkey from 1982 to 1993 was the real
external value of the Turkish Lira. Column
(1) shows the estimate of equation (11), in which the variable exch is significant with negative sign.
When we look at the signs of the multiplicative terms we observe that, market
concentration effect is not significant. However, the coefficients of multiplicative
term of degree of product differentiation and the dummy variable for the sectors
with high imported input dependency () are both significant with positive signs. We re-estimated
the equation eliminating the insignificant market structure variable and presented
the results in column (2).
|
||
|
|
|
|
(2.977) |
(2.96) |
Real Exchange Rate |
-0.125 |
-0.119 |
Market Concentration*Real Exchange Rate |
-0.060 (-0.351) |
---- |
Degree of product differentiation* Real Exchange Rate |
0.165 (3.722) |
0.420 (3.864) |
Dummy1*Real Exchange Rate |
-0.189 (-1.335) |
-0.190 (-1.343) |
Dummy2*Real Exchange Rate |
-0.172 (-1.150) |
-0.171 (-1.145) |
Dummy3*Real Exchange Rate |
0.278 (1.950) |
0.284 (2.013) |
R2 |
0.232 |
0.231 |
# of observations |
304 |
304 |
As we stated in previous section, a devaluation
of domestic currency may increase the relative domestic prices in the case
of high imported input dependency. Our empirical results strongly support
this hypothesis. The negative sign of the coefficient of exch indicates that devaluation of Turkish
Lira (TL) causes relative domestic prices to decrease. However, the positive
sign of the multiplicative term of shows
that high imported input dependency of some sectors limits this effect. Moreover,
the net effect of the devaluation of TL on RDP
turns out to be positive in those sectors. The degree of product differentiation
also limits the exchange rates effect on RDP.
These
results are important, because they are the indication of the fact that,
devaluation of domestic currency in Turkey, may increase the inflationary
pressure on many of the domestic industries due to their high imported input
dependency. As it is known, current exchange rate based stabilization
programme, government tries to control inflation by controlling the value of TL
against foreign currecies. Our findings strongly supports the hypothesis that
exchange rates and related industry specific prices are important determinants
of relative domestic prices, and hence, this programme will certainly reduce
the inflationary pressure on domestic producers in Turkey.
4.
CONCLUSION
In this
article, we developed a theoretical model aiming to analyze the link between
fluctuations in exchange rate and realtive domestic prices in an economy where
domestic industries use imported inputs. Our theoretical model shows that
extent of exchange rate pass-through on relative domestic prices is closely
related with the degree of substitutability between imported and domestic
goods, market structure, the share of imported inputs, the size of the market
and the cost of foreign firms. In particular, the extent of imported usage is
the crucial determinant of the direction of the relationship between exchange
rates and relative domestic prices. For instance, if the imported input usage
of a domestic industry is low, depreciation of domestic currency causes
relative domestic prices to decrease. However, high imported input dependency
of domestic industries limits this effect and, it is in fact possible to
observe an increase in relative domestic prices as a response to a devaluation.
These
findings are tested by using the 3-digit data on Turkish manufacturing sector
covering the time period 1982-1993. Empirical results strongly support
theoretical findings. The relative domestic prices in Turkey, in fact,
increases as a response to a devaluation of TL in industries which has high
imported input dependency. Considering the fact that, Turkish industry in
general is quite dependent on imported inputs, it is possible to say that a
large portion of Turkish manufacturing industry will benefit from exchange rate
based stabilization programme of Turkish government in terms of inflationary
pressure.
Acknowledgements
We thank Ertugrul
Tokdemir and Burç Ülengin for their comments and suggestions, and Alpay Filiztekin,
Cihan Yalçin and Merih Güner for providing some of the data for this paper.
All remaining errors, however, are solely ours.
BIBILIOGRAPHY
Athukorala, P. and J. Menon
(1995), “Exchange Rates and Strategic Pricing: The Case of Swedish Machinery
Exports”, Oxford Bulletin of Economics and Statistics,
57 (4): 533-546.
Baltagi, B. H. (1995), Econometric Analysis of Panel Data, (Chichester:
John Wiley and Sons).
Dornbuch, R. (1987), “Exchange
Rate and Prices”, American Economic
Review 77: 93-106.
Feenstra, R. (1989), “Symmetric Pass-Through of tariffs and Exchange Rates
under Imperfect Competition: An Empirical Test”, Journal
of International Economics 27:
25-45.
Feinberg, R. (1991), “The Choice of Exchange-Rate Index and Domestic Price
Passthrough”, Journal of Industrial Economics 39 (4): 409-420.
Feinberg, R. (1989), “The Effects of Foreign Exchange Movements on US Domestic
Prices”, Review of Economics and Statistics 71: 505-511.
Feinberg, R. (1986), “The Interaction of Foreign Exchange and Market Power
Effects on German Domestic Prices”, Journal
of Industrial Economics 35 (1):
61-70.
Green, W. H. (1993), Econometric Analysis, (New York: MacMillan
Publishing Com.).
Goldberg, P. K. and M. M. Knetter (1997), “Good Prices and Exchange Rates:
What have we learned?”, Journal of Economic Literature 35: 1243-1272.
Günçavdi, Ö. and B. Z. Orbay (1998), “Exchange Rate, Domestic Market Structure
and Foreign Trade: The Case of Turkey”, a paper presented at the Econometric
Society North American Meeting, Canada.
Günçavdi, Ö., H. Levent and
B. Ülengin (1997), "A Comparison of Alternative Models of Inflation to
Forecast High and Volatile Inflation. The Case of Turkey”, 18-20 September
1997 I.
METU International Conferences
on Economics (in Turkish).
Günes, M. (1998), Türk Imalat Sanayinde Yogunlasma Oranlarini
Belirleyen Faktörler 1980 – 1994 (The Determinants of Concentration Ratios
in the Turkish Manufacturing Industry, 1980 – 1994), Ankara: State Institute
of Statistics Publications.
Hsiao, C. (1986), Analysis of Panel Data, Econometric Society
Monographs, No. 11, (New York: Cambridge University Press).
Lee, J. (1997), “The Response of Exchange Rate Pass-through to Market Concentration
in a Small Economy: The Evidence from Korea”, Review
of Economics and Statistics 79
(1): 142-145.
Menon, J. (1995), “Exchange
Rate Pass-Through”, Journal of Economic
Survey, 9 (2): 197-231.
Metin, K. (1995), The Analysis of Inflation: the Case of Turkey
(1948-1988), Capital Market Board, Publication No: 20.
Özatay, F. (1997), “A Quarterly Macroeconomic Model for A Highly Inflationary
and Indebted Country: Turkey”, Yapi
Kredi Bankasi Research Department Discussion Paper Series No: 97/05.
State Planning Organisation,
SPO, (1987), Economic and Social Indicators
(1950-1997), Ankara.
Yang, J. (1997), “Exchange Rate pass-Through in US Manufacturing Industries”,
Review of Economics and Statistics LXXIX (1): 95-104.